HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    1/24

    r

    I

    THE ECONOMICS

    OF

    NATURAL

    RESOURCE

    USE

    John

    M

    Hartwick

    Queen s

    University

    Nancy

    D

    Olewiler

    Queen s U niversity

    tfj

    ARPER ROW, PUBLISHERS , New York

    Cambr idge Philadelphia San FrancIsco

    London Mexico City Sao Paulo Syd ney

    8 7

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    2/24

    Nature s resources

    are not

    so

    much

    an inheritance/rom our parents, as a loan/rom

    our

    children.

    We

    dedicate

    this

    book

    to

    our parents

    and children.

    Sponsoring Editor: John Greenman

    Project Editor: Mary G. Ward

    Cover Design:

    ohn

    Hite

    Text Art: Artset Ltd.

    Production: Debra Forrest

    Compositor: Progressive Typographers

    Printer and Binder: R. R Donnelley Sons Compan y

    THE ECONOMICS OF NATURAL RESOURCE USE

    Copyright © 1986 by Harper Row, Publishers, Inc.

    All rights reserved. Pri nted in the United States of America No

    part of

    his book

    may be used

    or

    reproduced in any manner whatsoever without written permission,

    except in th e case

    of

    brief quotations embodied in critical articles and reviews. For

    informati on address Harper Row, Publishers, Inc.,

    10

    East 53d Street, New York,

    NY

    10022.

    Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data

    Hartwick, John M.

    The economics of natural resource use.

    Includes bibliographies.

    1 Natural resources. 2 Environmental policy.

    I. Olewiler, Nancy D. II. Title.

    HC59.H3558 1986 333.7 13 85-14076

    ISBN 0·06-042695-0

    85

    86 87 88

    9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 I

    I

    r

    i

    1

    I

    T

    ONTENTS

    PREFACE xi

    1

    2

    3

    Approaching the Study

    o

    Natural Resource Economic

    Introduction, 1

    Decision-Making over Time, 3

    Interest Rate, 4 Compounding, 4 Discounting or Getting Present

    Value, 5 Techniques of Analysis, 7

    ,

    Property Rights and Natural Resource

    Use

    8

    Welfare Economics and the Role o Government, 11

    Resources in the Economies of the United States, Canada, and Other Nations

    Summary, 20

    Land Use and Land Value

    Introduction, 22

    The Concept o Economic Rent, 23

    Rent on Homogeneous Land, 24 Plots

    of

    Differing

    Quality 27 Institution al Arrangements: The Role

    of

    Market Structure and

    Property Rights in the Determination of Rent,

    31

    Location and Land Value 35

    The Price

    of

    an Acre

    of

    Land,

    35

    Efficient Land Use with Two Competing

    U ~ e s

    36

    Intermediate Goods and Mixing Land Uses,

    38

    Neoclassica

    Land Use Patterns,

    39

    Institutional Arrangements

    and

    Land Use

    Patterns, 42 Transportation Costs and Aggregate Land Rents, 45

    Summary, 46

    Nonrenewable Resource Use: The Theory o Depletion

    Introduction, 49

    The Theory of the Mine,

    Cl

    Extraction from a Mine Facing a Constant Price,

    51

    Profit Maximization

    for the Mine, 54 Quality Variation Within the Mine, 57

    Extraction by a Mineral Industry, 59

    The Hotelling Model,

    59

    Exhaustibility

    and

    Welfare: Demand Curves and

    Backstop Technology, 63 A Model

    of

    a Competitive Nonrenewable

    Resource Industry,

    65

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    3/24

    vi

    4

    5

    6

    CONTENTS

    Extensions of the Industry Model, 67

    Changes in Extraction Paths Under Altered Conditions 67 AnJncrease in

    Extraction Costs

    67

    A Rise in Interest Rates 68 The Introduction of

    Taxes 68 Declining Quality in the Stock

    70

    Deposits of Distinct and

    Differing Quality 72 Setup Costs for the Mine and Industry 74

    Summary, 77

    Market Structure and Strategy in Nonrenewable

    Resource Use

    Introduction,

    88

    Market Structure in a Static Environment, 89

    Monopoly versus Perfect Competition 89 Cournot versus Stackelberg

    Models o f Oligopoly 91

    Market Structure

    in

    a Dynamic Environment, 95

    The Monopoly Resource Supplier 95 Dominant Firms and Fringe Sellers:

    A Case of Oligopoly 100

    Backstop Technologies

    and

    Market Structure, 106

    A Backstop Owned by the Monopolist 106 A Resource Monopolist Facing

    a Competitive Backstop Technology 107 Strategic Behavior in Developing a

    Substitute

    109

    Recycling as an Alternate Source of Supply 112

    Market Structure and Common Pool Problems with Oil and Gas Resources, 113

    Summary, 117

    Uncertainty and Nonrenewable Resources

    Introduction, 119

    . Economics and Uncertainty, 120

    Uncertainty Concerning Stock Size 122

    Two Deposits of Unknown Size 125

    Uncertainty

    and

    Backstop Technologies, 127

    Uncertain Date of Arrival of he Backstop Technology

    131

    Option Values

    of Minerals and Coping with Price Uncertainty 132

    Exploration for New Reserves, 133

    General Issues and Externalities 133 Exploration and Risk

    Pooling 137 Exploration

    ofa

    Known Deposit

    of

    Unknown Size

    138

    Summary,

    141

    Economic Growth and Nonrenewable Natural Resources

    Introduction, 144

    Natural Resource Scarcity, 145

    Measures of Natural Resource Scarcity 147 Real Unit Costs 147 The

    Real Price of the Resource

    148

    Resource Rents

    151

    Concluding

    Comments 154

    Economic Growth and Depletable Resource Use 157

    The Derived Demand for Nonrenewable Resource Flows 158

    Models of Economic Growth with Depletable Resources

    161

    Normative

    Investing

    88

    9

    44

    I

    t

    I

    CONTENTS

    7

    8

    9

    Resource Rents and Intergenerational Equity 165 Population Growlh

    Pollution and Technical Progress 167 Positive Approaches to Economic

    Grqwth with Nonrenewable Resources 168

    Limits to Growth, 169

    Projections and Predictions 169 A Trend Displaying Arithmetic

    Growth

    170

    Geometric Growlh

    172

    The Limits to Growth

    174

    Summary 179

    Issues in the Economics

    of

    Energy

    Introduction, 183

    Short-Run Effects of Energy Price Increases, 189

    Long-Term Effects of High Oil Prices: Supply Effects,

    191

    Possible OPEC Actions: The Wealth-Maximizing Model 192 Possible

    OPEC Actions: The Target Revenue Model

    197

    Effects of Rising Oil Pric

    on Energy Supply 203 Estimation of Supply Curves of Nonrenewable

    Resources 205 Specific Energy Resources 2 0

    The Demand for Energy, 221

    The Importance pfEnergy in the Economy 222 Price Elasticities of

    Demand for EnergY

    224

    Energy Consumption and Conservation over

    Time

    228

    .

    Energy Policy

    and

    the Energy Crisis, 231

    Price Ceilings 233 Policies to Reduce Dependence on Oil Supplies 236

    Summary, 238

    The Economics of the Fishery: An Introduction

    Introduction, 243

    A Model of the Fishery,

    24El

    Fishery Populations: Biological Mechanics 247 The Bionomic Equilibrium

    in a Simple Model 252 Harvesting Under Open Access 255 The

    Industry Supply Curve for a Common Property Fishery 261 Socially

    Optimal Harvests under Private Property Rights 263

    Fishery Dynamics, 268

    The Discounting

    of

    Future Harvests 268 Dynamic Paths in the Fishery:

    The North Pacific Fur Seal 276

    Extinction of Fish Species, 2 4

    The Bioeconomics of he Blue Whale: A Case of Near

    Extinction 284 Socially Optimal Extinction

    287

    Summary, 287

    Regulation of the Fishery

    Introduction 292

    The Economics of Fishery Regulation, 293

    The OptirnalTaxes o n the Fishery 293 A Tax on the Catch 296 A

    Tax on Fishing Effort 298 A Quota on the Catch and Effort 300 So

    Ownership of he Fishery: The Cooperative 304

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    4/24

    viii

    1

    12

    CONTENTS

    Fishery Regulations in Practice, 304

    Fisheries Management Councils in the United States, 306 The Oyster

    Fishery, 310 Spanish Sardines, 314 The Pacific Halibut, 318

    Summary, 323

    Special Topics in the Economics of the Fisheries 326

    Introduction, 326

    Varieties of Biological Basics, 327

    Salmon, 327 Environmental Factors in Fishery Biological

    Mechanics 33 Interaction among Species 33

    International Fisheries, 340

    A Two-Country Model, 340

    Uncertainty

    in

    the Fishery, 343

    Summary, 344

    Forestry

    Use 348

    Introduction, 348

    Some Biological Basics of Trees

    and

    Forests,

    351

    The

    Optimal Rotation Period for the Firm, 355

    Another Approach to the Choice

    of

    Rotation Period, 360 Rotation Periods

    in Different Environments, 360 Optimal Harvests in a Mature Forest, 364

    The Forest Industry: Price Determination with Many Different Forest Types, 365

    The Relative Profitability of Forestry Use in Different Locales, 365 Effects

    of

    Taxes on Forestry Use, 367 Property Rights and the Incentive to

    Replant,

    368

    Forestry

    ~ r c t i c e s

    and Policies, 368

    Mean

    Annual Increments and Allowed

    Cuts

    in National

    Forests, 372 Policies and Practices

    of

    the

    U S

    National Forest

    Service, 374 The Social Losses from Public Forest

    Management, 376 Do Private Firms Harvest Too Quickly?, 378

    Summary, 379.

    An

    Introduction to Environmental Resources:

    Externalities

    and Pollution

    382

    Introduction, 382

    A Taxonomy of Externalities, 386

    Public versus Private Externalities 386 Externalities in

    Consumption, 394 Externalities in Production, 402

    Distribution Di mensions

    o

    Intermllizing Externalities 406

    Pollution Control Mechanisms, 4 6

    Topics in the Theory of Environmental Controls, 410

    Income

    Alternative

    Taxes versus Subsidies, 411 Taxes versus Standards, 414

    Summary, 421

    1

    /-

    r

    I

    I

    I

    I

    CONTENTS

    3

    Pollution Policy

    in Practice

    Introduction, 425

    Environmental Quality

    and

    the Valuation

    of

    the Marginal benefits from Pollu

    Abatement, 426

    General Issues, 426 Water Quality and Recreation Benefits, 427

    Bees and Blossoms, 432

    Standards versus

    Fees

    in Practice, 435

    France and the Netherlands: Fees for Emissions, 436 The,United States:

    Water Pollution Standards, 438

    Marketable Permits: The New Wave in Pollution Control?, . 442

    Institutional Background, 443 Characteristics of Marketable

    Permits,

    446

    The Ambient'Based ystem,

    448

    The Emissions-Base

    System, 449 The Offset System, 451 Costs of Alternative Permit

    Systems, 453 Acid Rain: Can Marketable Permits Help?, 455

    Summary, 457

    4 Governmental

    Regulations

    and

    Policy in Natural

    Resource

    Use

    Introduction, 461

    Promoting Efficiency

    and

    Equity

    in

    Natural Resource

    Use

    464

    Efficiency and Market Failure in a Static Economy, 465 Efficiency over

    Time, 469 Mitigating the Effects

    of

    Market Failures,

    471

    Second B

    Policies, 474 Equity Concerns, 475

    Regulatory Agencies and

    the

    Efficacy

    of

    Regulation,

    476

    Regulatory Agencies in the United States and Canada, 476 The Efficienc

    Regulation, 478 The Regulation and Deregulation

    of

    Natural Gas Prices

    the United States: A Case Study,

    482

    Concluding Remarks: Policy Formation and the Political Process, 491

    Summary; 493

    Appendixes

    References

    Author Index

    Subject Index

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    5/24

      8

    L ND USE ND LAND VALUE

    3. The derivation ofR involves summin g rent per acre over all acresor integrating over a series

    of infinitesimal circular rings or annuluses. Before integrating,

    R =

    XI 21lXYl

    Pl tx

    -

    ZIW) dx X2 21lXY2

    P2 -

    t2X

    -

    Z2W) x

    o Yl

    JX

    Y2

    and

    R in the text results after carrying

    out

    he integration operations. Below we maximizeR

    by differentiating with respect to Xl and X2

    and

    set the expressions equal to zero.

    4. An early statement of his was Mohri ng 1961). See the extensive discussion

    in

    Arnott and

    Stiglitz 1979).

    chapter

    Nonrenewable

    Resource Use

    The Theory

    of

    Depletion

    INTRODUCTION

    Nonrenewable resources include energy

    supplies-oil

    natural gas

    coal-and nonenergy minerals-copper nickel, bauxite, and zinc, t

    These resources are formed by geological processes

    that

    typically. ta

    years, so we can view these resources for practical purposes

    as

    having a

    reserves.

    That

    is, there is a finite amount

    of

    he mineral in the groun

    removed cannot be replaced.

    1

    Nonrenewability introduces some new

    issues into the analysis of production from the mine or well that do n

    production of reproducible goods such as agricultural crops.

    A mine manager must determine not only how to combine v

    inputs such as labor and materials with fixed capital as does the farm

    quickly to run down the fixed stock

    of

    ore reserves through extraction

    o

    A unit

    of

    ore extracted today means that less in total is available for to

    plays an essential role in the analysis. Each period is different, because t

    resource remaining

    is

    a different size. What we are concerned with in

    analysis of nonrenewable resources is how quickly the mineral is ext

    the

    flow

    of production is over time, and when the stock will be exhau

    In this chapter, we determine the efficient extraction path of he r

    amount extracted in each time period. First, we examine the behavior

    ual mine operator; We then examine how a social planner would exp

    deposit. Finally, we develop the extraction profile

    of

    a mining

    industr

    we assume that perfect competition prevails in every market. We deriv

    mineral output, prices, and rents over time under varying assumpti

    nature of he mining process. The competitive equilibrium over time i

    the socially optimal extraction path.

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    6/24

    5

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE

    USE

    THE THEORY

    OF

    DEPLETION

    Our initial moqel is very simple

    and

    abstracts c.onsiderably from reality so that

    we can identify and examine basic concepts.

    The

    assumptions are gradually relaxed

    so that we can deal with increasingly complex

    but

    more realistic models. Relaxing the

    assumption of perfect competition is done in Chapter 4 and of certainty in Chapter 5.

    In examining the mine's and industry's extraction decision, we also illustrate the

    effects on

    output

    and prices over time of changes in particular variables affecting the

    mining process. What will be the effect

    on

    extraction over time of, for example, a

    change in extraction costs, the introduction

    of

    setup or capital costs, different quali

    ties

    of

    ore, a change

    in

    the discount rate, the imposition

    of

    axes?

    THE TH ORY

    OF THE

    MIN

    We begin with a simple model

    of

    esource extraction from

    an

    individual mine which

    operates in a perfectly competitive industry. The mine owner will seek to maximize

    the present value of profits from mineral extraction in a

    manner

    similar to that of a

    manager

    of

    a plant producing a reproducible good. An output level must be chosen

    that

    maximizes the difference between total revenues - the discounted value of

    future extractions q q2 Q3 etc., inultiplied

    by

    price,

    p and

    total

    cost- the

    discounted value

    of

    dollars expended in getting each q out of the ground.

    The

    presence of the finite stock of

    the

    .mineral modifies the usual maximization condi

    tion; marginal revenue

    MR)

    equals marginal cost

    MC),

    in three

    fundamental

    ways.

    Suppose we compare farming to copper extraction.

    The

    owner of the copper mine

    faces

    an

    opportunity cost not encountered by the farmer. This is the cost of using up

    the fixed stock at any point in time, or being left with smaller rem aining reserves. To

    maximize profits, the operator must cover this opportunity cost of depletion. For a

    competitive firm manufacturing a reproducible good,

    the

    conditions for a profit

    maximum are to choose output such thatp( =

    MR)

    = Me The nonrenewable re

    source analogue requires p = MC he opportunity cost of depletion.

    How

    then

    would the mine owner measure this opportunity cost?

    t

    is the value of the unex

    tracted resource, a resource rent related

    to

    those discussed in Chapter 2.

    The second feature

    that

    differentiates nonrenewable resources from reproduc

    iblegoods concerns the value of he resource rent over

    time.

    Deciding how quickly to

    extract a nonrene wable resource is a type

    of

    nvestment problem. Suppose one has a

    fixed amount of money to invest in some asset, be it a savings account, an acre of

    land, a government bond, or the stock

    of

    a nonrenewable resource in the ground.

    Which asset is purchased (and held

    on

    to over time) depends on the investor's

    expectation of the rate

    of

    return

    on

    that asset----the increase in its value over time.

    The investor obviously wants

    to

    purchase

    the

    asset with

    the

    highest rate of return.

    However, in a perfectly competitive environment with

    no

    uncertainty, all assets

    must, in a market equilibrium, have the same rate of return.

    To

    see how this is so, consider

    what

    would

    happen

    if

    the economy had

    two

    assets, one that increased in value 10 percent per year, the other at 20 percent per year.

    Assume there is no risk associated with either

    asset

    No one would invest in the asset

    earning only 10 percent; everyone would want the asset earning 20 percent The price

    of

    the high-return asset would then increase,

    and

    the price

    of

    the low-return asset

    would decrease until their rates of return were equalized.

    THE THEORY

    OF

    THE MINE

    What

    exactly is

    the

    rate of eturn

    to

    a nonrenewable resource?

    Th

    to the mine is the resource rent-the value of he ore in the ground. W

    positive

    discount rate, the rent is positive

    and

    rises

    in nominal

    valu

    occurs. If the resource rent did

    not

    increase in value .over time,

    purchase the mine, because the rate

    of

    return

    on

    alternative assets w

    valuable.

    In

    addition, the owner of an existing deposit would

    attempt to

    . are as quickly as is technically feasible. Why should

    one

    hold on to ore

    that is increasing in value at a rate less than

    can

    be earned on, say, a sav

    Alternatively, if the value

    of

    he oreis growing at a rate in excess

    of

    w

    earn in an alternative investment, there

    is no

    incentive to extract at all

    ground is then more valuable to the mine owner

    than

    are extracted.

    To

    extraction then,

    the

    rental value of he mineral must be growing at th

    that

    of

    alternative assets.

    There is

    one

    final condition imposed ottthe mine owner that d

    with reproducible goods. The total

    amount

    of the natural resource

    time cannot

    exceed its total stock of reserves. We call this the stock

    c

    Let us draw thes.e strands together for the first time. Suppose a mi

    plan of quantities extracted roughly worked out by a rule of

    thumb

    make the extraction plan somewhat tighter. Should he extract one m

    in this year's liftings or leave it for next year's liftings. Ifhe takes it ou

    gets $10 profit, he can that profit (rent) in the

    bank

    at, say, 8 per

    1 O(1.08) = $10.80 next year. If he leaves it

    in the

    ground and takes

    it

    he foresees t h ~ he will get a different price

    and

    can reap a profit (rent)

    case he will

    make

    more money by deferring extracti on ofthe extra ton u

    (If

    he were

    to

    get only $10.75 upon extracting next year,

    it

    would

    currently

    and

    sell

    the are

    this year.) By doing this calculation repeat

    owner arrives at the best extraction plan year by year. Let us now

    important

    features of nonrenewable resource extraction in

    more

    deta

    Extraction

    from a

    Mine

    Facing a

    onstant Price

    One of the earliest economic analyses of mineral extraction appeared

    article by L. C. Gray. In Gray's model, the owner

    ofa

    small mine has

    much are

    to

    extract and for how long a period of ime. To solve this p

    made a number

    of

    simplifying assumptions. First, he assumed

    that

    th

    ofa

    unit

    of the mineral remained' constant (in real terms) over

    the

    lif

    The producer knew the exact

    amount of

    reserves

    in

    the mine (the s

    extraction. All the are was

    of

    uniform quality. Extraction costs

    then

    dep

    the quantity removed.

    We

    could

    view Gray's

    mine

    as a gigantic

    blQ.Ck of

    pure

    copper. P

    constant forever, while the marginal cost

    of

    cutting off a piece

    of

    coppe

    size of

    he

    piece cut off. If 1 ton ofcopper is cut off, it will cost $500

    to

    tons are cut offat once, the extraction costs could be $10,000. The econ

    is to cut. off appropriate quantities in each period in order to maximi

    value

    of

    profits available from the stock

    of

    the mineral. The mode

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    7/24

    5

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE USE: THE THEORY OF DEPLETION

    appeal, because in many mineral markets we do observe relatively constant prices

    over long periods of ime.

    To determine th e efficient extraction path for the mine, we start with a simple

    illustration. Suppose the mine will operate for two periods only.

    The mine

    owner

    must

    determine how

    much

    copper

    to

    chop off he block today

    and

    tomorrow, using

    the three conditions identified earlier.

    2

    For the two-period case, these conditions can

    be

    stated

    as:

    1. Price

    = M

    rent

    in

    each

    period(in

    present value).

    2. Rent today = the present value of rent tomorrow.

    3. Extraction today

    +

    extraction tomor row

    =

    total stock of reserves.

    The solution is shownin Figure

    3.1.

    Assume that the mine has aU-shaped

    average cost curve AC)

    and an

    upward':'sloping marginal cost curve

    MC)

    over some

    output range.

    3

    The constant price is shown as p.

    Output

    today is designated q O),

    output tomorrow is q

    T),

    where

    T

    signifies the end of the mining operation - the

    length of ime the mine operates (in this case, two periods). Given these curves

    and

    the total stock of ore; there will be a unique solution to the extraction problem that

    satisfies all three conditions.

    Me

    p ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~

    o

    q(t)

    Figure 3.1·

    Mineral

    extraction

    in

    two periods

    when

    there

    is

    a constant

    price.

    The mine

    operator extracts

    the amount

    q O) today and q T) tomorrow. The sum of q O) plus q T)

    completely exha usts the mine s reserves. Rents are R O) today and

    R T)

    tomorrow,

    where

    it

    must

    be

    the

    case that [R O)] 1

    )

    = R T),

    where

    r is

    the

    interest

    rate

    on

    alternative assets. Output levels

    q 1)

    and

    q 2)

    illustrate a plan that is not feasible

    because

    q 1) q 2)

    exceeds the total stock of reserves. .

    I

    I

    I

    r

    r

    I

    I

    I

    ·r

    l

    I

    f

    I

    .

    r

    I

    I

    t

    i

    I

    THE THEORY OF THE MINE

    The

    mine ·owner must pick

    an

    initial

    output

    level where

    p =

    M

    resource rent obtained at the output level q O)

    isR O).

    This is conditio n

    condition i defines rent as the difference between price and marginal c

    period, extraction must equal q(T)

    and

    the rent will be R(T).

    It

    must b

    R O)

    = R(T)/( r), where r is the market interest rate or discount

    return

    on

    any alternative asset.

    4

    This is condition

    2.

    Ifrents did

    not

    ri

    . interest extraction would not occur in both periods. If ent rose mor e s

    interest'rate the entire stock of ore would be extracted

    in

    the initial

    proceeds of he sale invested in some other assets whose value would ri

    interest (e.g., a savings account). If rent rose faster than the rate of nte

    stock

    of

    ore would be held

    in

    the ground until the last

    moment in

    extracted. In this case, the min e is worth more unextr acted because th

    on

    holding ore in the ground exceeds the return on alternative inves

    the rental value of he min e is growing

    at

    exactly the same

    rate

    as the

    assets extra ction will either be as fast as possible or deferred as lon

    Finaliy

    ,

    output

    today

    and

    tomorrow

    must

    be chosen such

    that q O

    where S is the stock of mineral reserves. This is condition 3. For a giv

    there will be only one level of initial output

    and

    hence final output t

    these conditions.

    To see that q O) is unique,. consider a case where the mine m

    initial

    output

    level greater.

    than q O),

    say

    q 1). The rent

    will

    then

    be

    R

    than R O). Output in the second period must then be such that

    R

    1) =

    This occurs at output q 2). The mine o wner will then have satisfied tw

    conditions

    1 and

    2),

    but

    notice that condition 3 is violated.

    The sum

    must exceed S because they are both larger than previous outputs

    extraction plan simply is

    not

    possible.

    The

    owner

    cannot

    extract

    more

    in the mine. Suppose the sum of q O) q(T) is less

    than

    S. Then the m

    remaining in the ground after extraction ceases, and revenue will

    unextracted ore. A slightly higher extraction r ate would yield additio

    This example can easily be extended to many periods of operation

    three conditions must be met. In addition, we can also tell when the m

    operation - how long Tis. Refer again to

    FigureJ.l.

    It s not a coincid

    is at the

    point

    where

    M =AC.

    This

    point

    is calleda

    terminal

    con

    nonrenewable resource extraction problem. It has a clear economic

    Consider any

    output

    level to the right

    or

    left of his point.

    foutput in

    t

    is to the right

    of q T),

    the last unit of he mineral extracted will yield a m

    p - C [q(T)] where C [q(T)] is marginal cost at q T). Each ton of he

    in the last period will contribute an average rent of

    pq(T)

    - C q T»

    q(T)

    or p - AC. By inspection, we can see

    thatthe

    average rent exceeds the

    It would therefore increase the present value of profits (rents)

    if

    the

    moved more tons of ore from the last period into the first period

    marginal rent isgreater

    than

    average rent

    at

    the last period

    MC

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    8/24

    5

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE USE: THE THEORY OF DEPLETION

    the optimal extraction plan must have the numb er ofton s

    in

    the last period such that

    average rent

    is

    equal to marginal rent; that

    is,

    pq(T)

    -

    C q T»

    p _ C (q(T»

    q(T)

    In terms ofFigure 3.1, average and marginal costs are equal at

    q(T),

    and

    q(T)

    is

    also that outp ut which combined with q O) exhausts the. mine. In the many-period

    case, the time to depletion will. be such that all three extraction conditions are

    satisfied, plus the terminal condition. This will determine a unique

    T.

    Table

    3.1

    provides a numerical example

    of

    the efficient extraction path in a many-period

    situation. Price

    is

    constant

    at

    $10, and marginal cost rises at a 45-degree line from

    M = 1 when quantity extracted in zero. In this example, 14.8 tons are extracted.

    over seven periods, with quantity declining toward the final period

    of

    extraction:

    q O) =

    3.9197,

    q 1)

    =

    3.4117,

    q 2)

    =

    2.853,

    ....

    Between consecutive periods

    (p

    -

    me)

    1 + r)

    = p

    - me where

    r =

    0.1, a

    10

    percent rate

    of

    interest. This is our

    condition that rent rises at the rate

    of

    interest. I n the last period

    p

    - me =

    p

    - ae,

    which is the condition for extracting the optimal

    amount in

    the last period (the

    terminal condition). Total profits evaluated

    in

    present value in period 0 are

    $94.4604. .

    Profit

    Maximization

    for the

    MineS

    rofit maximization

    involves making revenues large in relation to costs of produc

    tion. There

    is

    a series

    of

    evenues minus costs each year or period into the future. Each

    instant in time is slightly different, since depletion of he stock is occurring year by

    year. Discounting with the current interest rate makes each annual profit value

    comparable to others at the date at the beginning of extraction. In the absence of

    discounting, recall

    that

    profit in year 8

    in

    the future would be no t comparable with

    profit in year 11. Each nominal value is different at anyone point

    in

    time

    in

    the

    absence

    of

    discounting.

    The conditions discussed for the mine facing a constant price will also hold

    in

    this more general model. For the mine owner, total discounted profits (the present

    value

    of

    profits) are

    .

    ,=P

    q O)

    - C q O»

    +

    p •

    q J)

    -

    C q J»] J

    : r

    +

    [p

    Q 2)

    -

    C q 2»] J

    : r)

    +

    ...

    +

    [p

    . q(T) - C(q(T»] _l_)T 3.1)

    1 +

    r

    Equation

    3.1

    is what the mine owner wants to maximize subject to the stock con

    straint which requires that

    q O)

    + q(l) +

    ...

    + q(T)

    S

    (3.2)

    I-

    :;

    0-

    U

    -

    Q

    or:

    I

    C

    oS

    .2:

    ;<

    U

    CQ

    I

    oS

    u

    CQ

    0-

    Q,

    0-

    *

    Z

    :i

    -0 '100 '11 .0 V) 01

    e

    oo-NOV)

    ..... ~ r - O ' I

    i38

    ; ;NNNN

    ~ I I

    ' - ' I : l ,

    .

      '

    ... 0

    ell

    V)

    0 1 - 1.0

    o ...

    N M r - o o o o ~

    15

    o o o o \O r - O M

    ' ( ; lo

    - 0 ' 1

    ..... oor-r-

    ..

    '0

    0 0 0 '

    o o N

    ..... 01

    i:l S

    1.0 M V) ..........

    OO.nNOO..,fo.;

    ..... NNMM

    ~ p . .

    Po

    ]0

    +-' 0

    cu 0

    , :::I'':

    S

    0

    V)

    01

    .....

    \0

    $

    N M r - o o o o ~

    S\O

    o o o l . O r -O M

    V)

    .....

    01 .....

    oor-r-

    \0

    ~ . 8

    ooo .....

    o o N

    ..... OI N

    tl'5

    .... 1.0 M

    V)

    ..........

    0

    o o V ) N o o ~ O ' I 00

    'EPo

    ·....;NNMM

    :

    S

    ' 0

    ~ < l : l

    ' ' :

    c u ~

    PoOl)

    s s

    V)

    01 ..... 1.0

    ~ : 1 2

    N M r - o o o o ~

    o ...

    ' 0

    o o o l . O r -O M

    t l ~

    .... 01 ..... oor-r-

    .. ;>.

    ' 00

    .....

    o o N

    ..... 01

    ..... 1.0 M V) ..........

    Ocu

    00 V) N 00 01

    >

    ;Nc...)c...)..,f..,f

    '

    s

    § , ~

    V)

    - 0 1

    .... 0

    oo\OM--V)

    00

    ...

    0

    --MNO I\O

    :: :.s

    0 ' I ~ ~ ~ ; : : : l 8 1

    ' 0 ]

    o o M \ o ~ o o o o

    ~ o : j

    - ~ r -

    ..... V ) o

    g

    lJ

    00r- :00.n .n

    ~ c u

    < ]

    *

    1 . O v ) ~ M N ' O

    0

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    9/24

      6

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE USE: THE THEORY OF DEPLETION

    Equation (3.2) says that the sum ofthe quantities ofore extracted must not exceed the

    total stock of reserves available. The symbols used in Equati ons (3.1)

    and

    (3.2(are

    defined as follows: .

    p

    is

    the constant price per ton for the mineral

    q(t) is the quantity extracted in time t

    qq(t)]

    is the total cost

    of

    extracting

    q(t)

    tons

    of

    the mineral

    t indicates the time period. Today is time 0, the next period is time

    1,

    and so on.

    One can think of these periods as years

    r is the discount or nterest rate, which is assumed to remain constant over time

    T

    is the

    number of

    periods over which the mine will be operated

    S

    is the total stock

    of

    mineral reserves

    All variables are interpreted in real (constan t dollar) terms.

    Maximizing this profit stream subject to the stock constraint on total output

    yields .

    p - c (q(O» = k

    Cr

    [p-c (q(1))] k

    C

    r

    p

    - c (q(T))]

    =

    k

    (3.3)

    where c' means

    dC/dq

    and kis a constant dependent on the stock size S

    (k s

    called the

    shadow price of a unit of stock). The principle in action here is that the discounted

    value

    of

    he marginal

    ton

    taken

    out in

    any period

    mustbe

    the same for

    an

    extraction

    program to be profit-maximizing. If his were not the case, the mine operator could

    increase the return to the mi ne by shifting production to where the marginal ton earns

    a higher discounted value. p - c (q(t» is the value of he marginal or last ton taken

    out in period t.

    (1/1

    + r)t[p - c (q(t»] is its discounted value.

    . For adjacent periods in time we have

    (

    1 t

    (

    1

    t+l

    1 +

    r

    . [p -

    c (q(t»]

    = 1 +

    r

    [p - c (q(t + 1)]

    or

    [p -c (q(t + 1»] - [p - c (q(t»]

    =r

    [p

    -

    c (q(t»]

    (3.4)

    wh ch says

    that

    the percentage change

    in

    p -

    c'

    between periods

    must

    equal the rate

    ·of mterest.

    p

    - c' is the

    rent

    on the marginal ton extracted. So

    we

    have the basic

    ~ f f i c i e n c y condition: The percentage change in rent across periods equals the rate of

    lnterest. .

    The terminal condition requires. that the quantities chosen are those which

    maximizt; discounted total profits so that the average profit in the last period equals

    the margmal profit on the last ton extracted. This tells us how to terminate the

    r

    I

    THE THEORY OF THE MINE

    sequence q(1), q(2), q(3). This condition combined with the stock c

    sure that the sum of the qs equals the original stock. These two con

    pq(T)

    - C(q(T» = p _ c [q(T)]

    q(T)

    q(l) + q(2) + + q(T) = S

    These two conditions, in addition to th e percentage change in rent

    the profit-maximizing number of periods over which to exhaust th

    Now

    we turn to mines with

    an

    ore quality which declines as e

    deeper into the mineral material

    .

    We are going to associate costs o

    processing with each unrefined

    on,

    not with a batch

    of

    homogen

    did above. We no longer have a large homogeneous block of coppe

    ,

    .I

    Quality Variation Within the ine .

    In the previous section, it was assumed that the cost of extraction r

    units of ore were extracted at anyone time. Suppose now that the ore

    pure cop per as before, but consists

    of

    metal

    and

    waste rock. The me

    throughout the waste rock in

    e a m s

    of varying thickness. The min e o

    to extract from t he thickest seams first, where the ratio of metal to w

    highest. Suppose the deposit is laid down with richest seams on top. A

    mined, the thic ker seams are depletedand more waste rock must be r

    increasingly thinner seams. Mining costs rise per unit of metal p

    because the metal content ofthe ore diminishes while the rock conten

    means

    that the

    marginal cost

    of

    extracting

    and

    processing

    each ton

    o

    Extraction costs per ton shift up (increase) as subsequent am

    extracted. The flow condi tion for efficient extraction of he mineral (

    2, or Equati on 3.4) is unchanged, but now holds fo r a single ton of

    quality (seam thickness). The mine owner can no longer slide down

    curve by extracting smaller amounts of ore over time to satisfy th

    efficient extraction because the marginal cost

    of

    extraction increas

    each incremental ton of ore processed. To see what happens to the e

    this case, we turn to Figure 3.2.

    The mine represented in Figure 3.2 illustrates a case where o

    tinuously decreasing, and we are examining extraction over two

    There are thus two curves of extraction cost per ton, one for period

    period

    (t +

    1), where the curve for (t

    + 1)

    lies everywhere above

    indicating that it will· cost more to extract and process additional

    time.

    The

    mine owner must determine how

    much

    ore to extract

    (t + 1) by following the flow condition.

    The

    quantity extracted in

    such that the rent on the last ton n the period will be exactly equal to

    could obtain

    if

    extracted hi the next period, discounted by

    1

    + r

    Figure 3.2, the rent on the marginal ton in he first panel ofthe figure

    if

    output

    is

    chosen at q(t) and the price is

    p(t). If

    he mine o wner is

    between extracting the marginal ton in period

    t

    or in period (t + 1), i

    ~ ' - - -

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    10/24

    58

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE

    USE:

    THE THEORY OF DEPLETION

    p t+

    I) I- c____ -_____

    a

    p t)1---------- ------

     

    d

    o q t)

    o

    q t + I

    Period

    t

    Period t

    +

    I

    Figure 3.2 . Quantity

    q t)

    in period

    t

    is set so that distance

    ab

    equals distance cd divided by 1

    +

    . The

    marginal ton in period

    t

    gets rent ab and would get rent cd if it were extracted

    in

    period

    t +

    1

    that the rent in

    t + 1

    is equal to

    cd,

    where

    cd

    = ab 1

    + r).

    The marginal ton in

    period

    t

    is, we emphasize, the least marginal ton in period

    t+

    1 because now

    every

    ton

    is of a different quality or has a different extraction and processing cost.

    This is what is illustrated by the higher marginal cost curve in the second panel of

    Figure 3.2.

    The important implication of this analysis is that the market price must rise

    over time if extraction

    of

    lower-quality, higher-cost ore

    is

    to occur. If the mineral

    price does

    not

    rise to

    p t

    +

    1

    in

    the

    period

    t

    +

    1 ,

    no extraction will occur

    in

    that

    period. Extr action will end with

    p

    ) equal to the extraction cost on the last ton taken

    out in period

    t.

    This possibility gives rise to another important distinction about the

    .

    end of

    the mining operation. In the case

    of

    uniform ore quality,

    we

    argued that

    mining would cease when all the ore was removed. We

    can

    call thisphysicaldepletion

    or exhaustion.

    Suppose, however, that the ore is_not of uniform quality and the costs of

    extracting additional units rise, as Figure 3.2 shows. If he market price does not rise

    sufficiently to ensure that extraction proceeds from one period,to another, the mine

    will shut down. Ifin period t + 1 the price is constant atp t), ore will be extracted to

    the point that

    p t)

    equals extraction cost. The mine is then said to have

    economic

    depletion in period t.

    t

    simply does not pay

    he

    mine owner to extract

    any

    ore beyond

    , the quality indicated at

    q t),

    given the extraction cost curves

    and

    the price

    p t).

    A

    higher rate of return can be' earned by taking the rent,

    ab, and

    investing it in an

    alternative asset which earns the market interest rate of r percent per year.

    In

    a many-period model, the length

    ofthe

    extraction period will be determined

    by the time path ofprices.

    For

    two prices

    inany

    consecutive periods, there will be only

    one· value

    of

    cost per ton and hence output that satisfies the flow condition. The

    optimal life

    of

    the mine, the length of time to depletion (whether economic

    or

    physical), will then be determined by linking together quantities over subsequent

    periods until the flow condition no longer is satisfied, or the mine runs out

    of

    ore.

    .

    I

    ..;.,

    I

    EXTRACTION BY A MINERAL INDUSTRY

    Mines frequently h ~ v valuable by-products. The mining of n

    yields profitable amounts of gold and platinum. It is straightforwa

    model of the mi ne to incorporate this s ituation. Valuable rock, So

    that for each scoop of size Q, there is K Q of nickel and G Q ofgold

    suppose that costs rise with the amount of rock, Q, processed. ForPK

    . or nickel, and PG gold, we get a revised pricing rule for optima

    (

    1

    t (

    ,dK dG·

    d e

    1 + r PK dQ t) +PG dQ t) - dQ t) = constant fo

    Now a weighted sum

    of

    prices net ofcosts increases at the rate

    of

    nte

    owner to be maximizing the discounted present value

    of

    profit:

    marginal cost

    of

    hoisting quantity Q t).

    We haveseen that when quality variation is introduced in eit

    above thata simple rule such as rent rising at the rate of nterest m

    in an essential way. In other words, simple formulas are inadequate f

    real world extraction programs. Fimi.lly, note that because Gray's mo

    firm, there is no discussion of he resource market and how (or if) m

    rise to satisfy the flow condit ion and allow produc tion to occur ove

    ine this important issue, we now turn to a model of a mineral indu

    EXTRACTION BY A MINERAL INDUSTRY

    The Hotelling Model

    In 1931, Harold Hotelling wrote a classic paper which examined th

    tion of a nonrenewable resource from the viewpoint

    of

    a social plan

    had

    as its goal

    the

    maximization

    of

    social welfare from the produc

    The model was at the industry level rather than that ofthe single min

    Hotelling arrived at the same condition for the efficient extractio

    namely, that the present value of a unit of a homogeneous but f

    mineral must be identical. regardless of when it is extracted. This

    conditions 1 and 2, which we call thejlow condition. Together wi

    straint and terminal condition, the optimal extraction plan for th

    resource can be determined at the indust ry level as well as for the

    Hotelling viewed the problem of

    how to extract a fixed st

    resource from the vantage point of a government social planning

    showed

    that

    a competitive industry facing the same extraction co

    curve as the government, and having perfect information a bout res

    arrive

    at

    exactly the same extraction

    path

    for the minera1.

    6

    The

    ef

    path determi ned by each firm acting independently in the competi

    yield the socially optimal extraction path. We first examine the pl

    and then show why it is achieved in a competitive industry. As bef

    simplifying assumptions are made and then gradually modified t

    with practical relevance. .

    When we deal with an industry rather than a single mine, the m

    no longer be· treated as a constant. Rather, it is assumed that the

    negati vely-sloped demand curve. The greater the industry output, th

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    11/24

    60

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE USE: THE THEORY

    OF

    DEPLETION

    will have to b e if we are to have an equilibrium

    in

    any mineral market at any given

    point

    in

    time. Hotelling assumed that prices would adjust so that a mineral market

    would be in equilibrium at every point in time; supply must always equal dem and.

    7

    We can think of the Hotelling model as examining world production

    of

    oil, nickel,

    copper, or some other mineral. As before, the stock of mineral reserves is of known

    size, and all units of the mineral are homogeneous. We assume a unit of the stock

    costs c dollars to extract and refine and that this cost is constant for all units of the

    ~ t o c k in the reserve endowment, S. Once again, it is as

    if

    we had a huge block

    of

    copper that cost c per

    ton

    to chip off. We want to find the rate of extraction

    that

    maximizes social welfare

    and

    completely exhausts the stock.

    (If

    c

    =

    0, the analysis is

    qualitatively unchanged.

    If

    c

    ncreases with the quantity extracted, we are back with

    Gray's cost assumption, which is an unnecessary minor complication at this point.

    See question 4 at the end of the chapter.)

    The

    problem is to maximize society's wealth

    W) or net

    return from mineral

    extracti on, which is defined' as ' '

    W = B q O»

    +

    B q 1» C

    r

    +

    B q 2)) ( 1 ,)

    + ... + B q T)) CJ (3.7)

    Again, there is the,resource stock constraint which requires that

    (3.8)

    q O) +

    q(l)

    + q 2) +

    . . .

    +

    ( T ) ~ S

    B

    q t»

    is the consumer plus producer surplus obtained n period

    t

    from the extraction

    ,

    of

    output,

    q(t).

    This social surplus is simply the area und er

    the demand

    curve up to

    quantityq(t) and

    above the constan t costs of extracting

    q t).

    This problem canbe solved in a manneranalogous to that presented previously.

    As before, the solution requires

    that

    he flow condition, terminal condition, and stock

    constraint be met. The crucial distinction between Hotelling's model and Gray'sis

    that

    we must examine the

    demand

    curve explicitly

    and

    derive a unique price for the

    resource

    in each

    period the mineral ind ustry operates.

    In

    addition, we

    can

    make the

    stronger statementabout the socially optimal as opposed to just the mine's efficient

    extraction path. 'We now derive the solution to the maxim ization of Equati on (3.7)

    subject to the stock constraint, Equati on (3.8), for a linear demand curve.

    In maximizing social welfare, the pl anner must decide what the net benefits are

    of

    extracting some

    of

    the mineral today as opposed

    to

    tomorrow. Therefore, the

    planne r will want to measure the change

    in

    the social surplus as one more unit of he

    mineral is produce d today. Consider Figure 3.3.

    The

    social surplus for the last unit

    extracted is simply the difference between the market price and the marginal cost of

    extraction, c. If q t) is extracted

    in

    period

    t,

    society gains

    the amount

    for

    the

    q(t)th

    unit extracted and the amount under the demand curve

    and

    above c for all previous

    or

    inframarginal units extracted. How muchwill the planner choose to extract

    in

    each

    period?

    As before, the flow condition provides an answer. To maximize social welfare, it

    must

    be the case

    that

    the ne t benefit to'society fr'om the last

    unit

    extracted

    in

    each

    EXTRACTION BY A MINERAL INDUSTRY

    p t) I ~ - - - - - - - -p t

    +

    1) r ~ ~

    c r ~ ~ b L _

    q t)

    Period

    t

    (a)

    D

    .i

    q t

    Period

    (b)

    Figure

    3.3 Rent per ton

    in

    period

    t is

    distarlce

    8?(1

    +

    ) = de.

    Price

    is

    higher in period

    t

    +

    1

    m an[d

    (ent per ton

    in

    period

    t

    +

    1

    Yields the optimal path of q s to extract.

    Ing p t)

    - c] 1

    +

    )

    = [p t +

    1) -

    period

    .is

    exactly equal in present value ter .

    otherwIse would entail foregoing

    th

    . ms In each penod

    of

    e

    net benefit of he marginalunit extr: ~ ~ ~ I m . u m benefits possible. A

    the case that the present value ofth c e IS SImply the resource ren

    F th e rent on the

    marginin

    e h .

    or , e two-pe nod case,

    q(t)

    and

    q(t

    + 1)

    ,

    ac

    peno

    ,

    must

    be chosen

    such tha

    p t) - c

    =

    [pet

    +

    1) '- c] _1_)

    . : 1

    +

    r

    F I g u ~ e .

    3.3 i,llustrates one pair

    of

    out

    uts ,

    . ,

    .

    condItIOn gIven

    D,

    the

    demand

    c p d

    or

    the two

    ?enods WhICh

    as.

    can be s.een in Figure 3.3, that ~ ~ ~ :

    c t n ~

    r. N o t I c ~ the fl?w.co

    WIth

    a statIOnary demandcurve

    th ,

    I era pncemustnse over tIm

    if

    he

    quantity extracted

    d e l i n ~ s

    ~ : . ~ ~ ; ; ; : y price, and hen,: th

    must be less than that in period

    t

    t .

    h e r e f o r ~

    extractIOn

    Equation (3.9). ' 0 ensure that thepnce rises just e

    We can rewrite Equat ion (3.9) to obtain

    [pet

    + 1)

    - c]

    + [pet) -

    c]

    . . [p t) -

    c]

    = r

    Wntten In this, form we see that as p . .

    eq It h , ce nses rent per ton g

    .

    ua

    0

    t e rate o

    nterest. This is often re fe r i r ~ w ~ ov

    SImply

    Hotelling s

    rule. We sketch the • i c ~ ed. to Hotellmg s

    r

    path shown is the one that

    rna

    p. path In FIgure 3.4. How

    ren.ts

    must

    grow

    at

    the rate

    of

    ~ ~ : ~ ~ ~ s

    M ~ I h l

    welfare?

    All

    HoteUing's

    whIch satisfy Hotelling's rule? Yes

    b'

    t Ig

    t.

    there be dozens of diffe

    the help

    of

    he stock

    o n s t r a i ~ t

    an'd ~ r ~ m q u e

    p ~ t ~ of

    output ca.n

    stant, the planner,will want to ensure that ~ ~ o n ~ I t I O n .. f x t r ~ p t I O

      e mIneral IS removed

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    12/24

    62

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE USE: THE THEORY O DEPLETION

    p L ~ ~ ~

    $

    per ton

    2

    3

    4

    T

    o

    Time

    .

    ..

    b t n periods

    t

    a rate equal to r the

    Figure 3.4 P r i c ~ ~ i ~ U I S d c o s t c ~ s p r : ~ ~ S i ~ 9 ~ ~ ~ o n e n t i a I l Y t rate r n the optimal

    rate of nterest. This Yle s a ren

    program of extraction. . . .

    . fi in rents. The constant cost s s u m p ~ l n

    in the gro ;lnd, ~ h e mme w n ~

    w ~ l

    t ; ~ ~ e ;osts the same to extract (in nommal

    is crucialm thIS a : g u m ~ n t ac um net to leave ore behind. We know tha t the

    terms); therefore,

    It

    cannot pay the

    p l ~ n

    . d must exactly equal the total stock

    . sum of he amounts extracted m each tIme peno "

    of the mineral reserves S) . . 3 h t 'th the linear demand curve there

    We can a l ~ o

    ee, f r ~ m

    FIgure ? i ~ i ~

    :

    buy more of he mineral, The price?

    some price, call It

    p,

    at

    h l ~ h

    no one

    t

    that

    e m n d

    for the good is choked off at

    thIS

    is often called the

    choke

    przce,

    mean

    have the stock

    of

    the mineral

    go

    to zero at

    point. Ideally, the planner would see to Therefore the plann er would seek to have

    exactly the point that demand goes ~ r o d t h e r w i s ~ deprives society of maximum

    the last unit of output extracted at p. Of 0 0

    benefits. - .ven the fixed stock

    S,

    to find just that

    We can then

    w o ~ k

    b a ~ k w a r d fr.om Pci line so that rent increases at rate rand

    initial output q O), whIch WIll, over 1 ~ ~ i one such extraction and hence rent path

    outputs sum to the stock of reserves. y . 1 rplus available to society and hence

    exists.

    It

    will yield the r g e ~ t ~ m o u n t ~ ~ s ~ ~ ~ J:termine the length dftime the i ~ e

    be the optimal plan. In

    d d l t 1 o n ~

    we c h' h the price path intersects price p

    wIE

    operates. In Figure 3.4, the pomt at w lC . file' T Once the price reaches p,

    determine the unique duration f t h e h e x t ~ a c t l O ~ ~ ~ ~ x t ; a c ~ i o n will cease. Extraction

    there will be no more demand for t e mmera , .

    ends at time T.

    .

    1 dition discussed earlier is also met

    at T.

    T h ~ r ~ n t

    Note also that the termma con

    n the average ton at

    T.

    This condItIon

    on the m a r g i ~ a l

    to.n

    must be equal to the

    r e

    0

    T

    must equal zero. Table 3.2 gives

    .a

    also implies m thIS case that .output at tl. . th for the industry. Rent per ton IS

    numerical example of an

    o p t 1 ~ a l e x t r a c t 1 o ~ p: +

    r

    = pet + 1)

    _

    c.

    This is the con

    pet) - cand for consecutive e n o ~ s

    p t)

    - T ~ ~ deJand curve intersects the vertical

    dition that rent rises at the rate of mterest. .

    EXTRACTION BY A MINERAL INDUSTRY

    ;<

    Table 3.2

    AN INDUSTRY EXTRACTION EXAMPLE*

    pet) - c

    pet)

    q t)

    (p

    -

    c)xq

    6

    9

    10

    0

    0

    5

    8.181818

    9.181818

    .818182

    6.6942162

    4

    7.4380165

    8.4380165

    1.5619835

    11.618059

    ·3

    6.761833

    7.761833

    2.2388167

    15.134111

    2

    6.1471211

    .7.1471211

    2.8528789

    17.536992

    1

    5.5882919

    6.5882919

    3.4117081

    19.065621

    0

    5.0802654

    6.0802654

    3.9197346

    19.913292

    14.802654

    I

    A

    stock of

    14.8

    tons

    is

    extracted· over seven periods resulting in the maximization of t

    consumer surplus. Extraction cost per ton is constant at $1 and the industry demand curve

    is

    linea

    back from period 6 to period

    O

    (Parameters: r 1, c

    =

    1, q

    = 10

    - p, S 14.802654.)

    .i

    axis at

    p

    =

    10, when

    q

    = O

    This a l u ~

    p

    = 10

    is the

    choke

    price.

    Ove

    14.803 tons are extracted.

    Totalprojii

    evaluated at period 0 in prese

    $75.20. (We have no t illustrated that in period 6;

    p 6)

    - c

    = [B q 6»

    or marginal welfare from extracting

    q 6)

    equals average. welfare.

    tricky, since

    q 6) =

    0 in order to satisfy this basic end point conditi

    Exhaustibility and Welfare: Demand Curves and Backstop Technology

    What would happen if he world were to run out ofoil or any nonrene

    one day? What does the Hotelling model tell us about this occurrence

    complete exhaustion on society depends on the technology of produ

    resources

    in

    production and can be reflected in the demand curve for

    crucial question is whether substitutes for the resource exist or whethe

    so necessary to the production processofother goods that once it is de

    goods will also cease to be produced. Our model with the linear dem

    choke price says that a substitute exists. The choke price is that pric

    users of he good will switch entirely to the use of he substitute good.

    may be another nonrenewable resource such as oil shale as a substitu

    tional crude oil, or it may be a reproducible good such as solar e

    substitute exists, society and economic systems will not collapse wh

    out; they will shift to the substitute commodity.

    What ifthere isno substitute for the depletable resource? In this s

    available quantities of he resource dwindle, prices would begin to ris

    We can characterize this with a nonlinear demand curve, sayan isoela

    does not have a positive intercept

    9

    (see Figure 3.5). We will not have

    running out of the resource in this case, because we never will in fin

    society's viewpoint, however, this

    is

    not a very desirable· situation b

    suggests is that

    as

    the resource quantity extracted gets smaller and sm

    will rise to higher levels. We can thin k of extracting oil by the bucket

    and finally by teaspoons and eyedroppers while the price climbs contin

    infinity. This

    is

    asymptotic depletion.

    Asymptotic

    means that two l

    each other more and o ~ e closely

    as

    time passesbut never touch.) This

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    13/24

    6

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE USE: THE THEORY OF DEPLETION

    Price

    p t)

    Quantity q t)

    . . elastic demand curve. As the quantity

    FlgtUrcet ed5 i ~ ~ i l : ~ e s , the price rises toward infinity. Ex

    ex ra . . f

    t

    t'me

    haustion does not occur In

    1m

    e I '

    . l' t The co·nventional view is that

    .

    th

    r un rea is

    IC.

    a mathematical m o d e ~

    but

    is

    ra

    edb. the production

    of

    a substitute r o d u c ~ .

    exhaustion of most mmerals is f o l l o ~ e

    Y d

    t . nto the extraction model. It is

    We can incorporate t h ~ substitute p r ~ a

    ~ c ~ s t o p

    technology a technique for

    common to think of he substitute product a fl power that becomes feasible to

    producing energy at a

    ~ o n s t a n t

    cost ~ ~ c ~ a ~ ~ i ~ : ~ ~ ~ h e s a certain level. Feasible here .

    implement once the pnce o r o n v ~ n 10 . cover their costs.

    10

    Suppose the back

    means that the producers the

    a c k s : ~ f t ~ ~ n

    commodity at a price of 2, per t o ~

    stop technology· can p r o v ~ d e the s u ~ d ced with cons tant costs. ThiS case is

    forever,because the substitute can e pro u .

    illustrated

    in

    Figure 3.6.

    Price

    Z

    ________

    Backstop supply

    D

    Quantity

    q

    I provides a resource substi-

    Figure 3.6 The

    a c k s t o ~ I ~ ~ ~ : t ~ ~ ~ ~

    point at which price per ton

    tute at $Z per ton. Rebntt,w

    t

    It take over as exhaustion occurs at

    equals$Z and the

    s,u

    s I u e

    that joinin g of price and

    Z.

    .

    EXTRACTION BY A MINERAL INDUSTRY

    All demands below Z are satisfied by

    flows

    from the nonren

    stock and those

    at Z are supplied by the backstop technology. One

    demand curve in Figure 3.6

    as

    one for energy, derived from conven

    The backstop is energy from fusion or solar power (two possible su

    For a planner controlling both sources of supply - the exhaustib

    backstop technology - the optimal program will be to consider Z a

    for conventional oil and to arrange to exhaust this oil in the Hotellin

    out in the previous section. At the moment of exhaustion, price will

    per ton and the backstop technology brought on line. 11

    Model of a ompetitive Nonrenewable Resource

    Industry

    We have argued that the socially optimal extraction path would

    planner organized production in the industry. Would a decentraliz

    industry replicate the socially optimal program

    of

    extraction? Supp

    large number of mines or oil wells, each owned by a different perso

    owners coordinated their actions, we would have what is called

    competitive setting. Each owner would be faced with this decision: Sh

    sell a ton

    of

    ore this period and earn p t)

    -

    cdollars

    of

    profit, or shoul

    next period and extract, sell, and receive p t

    +

    1) - cdollars of prof

    the prices

    p t)

    and p t +

    1)

    were such that Equation (3.9) was

    sa

    p t)

    - c

    = p t + 1)

    - c)/ 1

    +

    r), each owner would be indifferent

    this period

    or

    next. Since all owners

    and

    deposits are identical (ther

    differences among mines), all are indifferent.

    If there was a general tendency to wait until next period by

    out put would fall and the curre nt price would rise. Sellers would th

    able to sell now and

    put

    their rents (

    or

    profits) into

    an

    asset earning

    r

    was a tendency to sell a lot ofore in the period, however, the current

    and

    mine operator s would be reluctant to sell until future periods. Th

    conditi on will be met by each firm seeking to maximize profits to ens

    each period, and the market forces of supply and demand will

    conditiop is met.

    Will a competitive industry which is on an equilibrium path

    optimal terminal condition? To show that it does, we assume that th

    price paths were not optimal then argue that this cannot happen in th

    model. If he price path were not the optimal path, there would be aj

    up or down at the transition to the backstop technology. Consider Fi

    tion commences at t = 0 with an initial price of p(O). The rent in

    R(O)

    F

    p(O) - C, grows at rate r utitil the resource is exhausted at tim

    that at T, the market price ofthe resource appears to have risen abov

    occur, because with the backstop technology, no consumer will pay

    the resource. It therefore means that the resource will be economic

    time

    T

    which

    is

    less than

    T.

    But this cannot be a plan that maximizes profits, because ore w

    ground

    that

    could have been extracted.

    If

    all firms know that th

    emerging, theywill alter their extraction plans to shift production to

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    14/24

     

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE USE: THE THEORY

    OF

    DEPLETION

    P

    I

    I

    I

    I

    I; per

    ton

    I

    I

    I

    pCO)

    I

    I

    p (O)

    I

    I

    R (O)

    I

    c

    teO)

    T T

    Time

    . . um down

    in

    the price at the time of

    Figure

    3.7 A pnce path ~ t h

    ~ i ~ n

    :OUld be shifted away from later pe-

    e x h a u s t i o ~ c a n n o ~ occur: dX p revent economic depletion at T .

    riods and Into earlier peno

    . .. '(0) which yields the

    . 111 wer the 1mtlal pnc e

    o

    say

    p

    , _ .

    increase in curre nt productIOnWI ; h exhaustion occur at precisely p. A SImilar

    rent R (O). t will grow at rate ran . ave h - that is firms run out

    of

    ore before

    ment applies if the price path fmls to reac p,

    argu b lemented

    the backstop technology can e

    1 ~ p th

    t all' mine operators have perfect foresight

    What these

    a r g u m ~ n t s r e ~ U l r e

    1S .

    To

    be able to see

    that it

    is profitable. o

    about the price

    of

    the

    m e r a ~

    m all

    pen

    .

    d' viduals must know what the pnce

    shift production from one penod to the other, ~ a ~ decades it is difficult

    to

    imagine

    will be Given that mines can produce for seve ' d o r de'centralized opera tion of

    . . h

    t

    es the centra

    1ze

    that perfect foresIght c arac e ~ z d that marke t forces will ensure that

    mineral markets. Some c o n o m ~ s t s haveha:gued 1 n decentralized situations, even 1f

    'l'b . w1ll be ac

    1eve

    . ' .

    perfect foresight eqUlI

    num

    d fi .

    nt

    information. Ifperson i s foreSIght 1S

    some participants in the market have e C1e, , ,

    l

    I

    EXTENSIONS

    OF THE

    INDUSTRY MODEL

    deficient relative to person} s,} could make a profit by signing a cont

    , from

    i

    in the future at specific conditions. The informational defi

    competed away by the forces

    of

    profit maximization and free entry i

    We now consider some modifications

    of

    the basic model, but' still

    participants act with perfect foresight. (Imperfect information i

    Chapter

    5.)

    EXTENSIONS OF THE INDUSTRY MODEL

    Changes in Extraction Paths Under Altered Conditions

    We will show how the price and extraction paths of a competit

    affected by: (1) a rise in the cons tant costs of extraction; (2) an increa

    (discount) rate; and (3) the introduction of axes. In each case, we c

    rium paths under two different assumptions. Biagrammatic techniq

    to

    derive the results.

    n Increase in Extraction Costs

    In

    Figure 3.8, we examine the case where the costs

    of

    extraction, whi

    are higher than initially assumed. How will these higher costs affec

    and price paths? In , this and all subsequent cases,

    we

    look

    at,

    the

    extraction had yet occurred. We could modify the results

    if he cost (o

    ter) change occurred at some time after the mine had begun to o

    situations, it will matter whether the mine owner antic ipated the cha

    f

    a d

    p ~ ~ ~

    per ton

    p (O)

    p(O)

    c f----_+_------------_+_---+-----

    c f 4 ~ _ _ _ T

    teO)

    I

    I

    T

    Time

    Figure 3.8 The comparative statics

    of an

    increase

    n

    extraction costs

    effect on the price path. If costs of extraction increase from c toe , the m

    industry will respond by reducing output

    in

    the initial period so that th

    source price rises fromp(O)

    top (O).

    Production s then increased again

    in

    periods. A higher extraction cost will lengthen the time

    to

    depletion.

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    15/24

      8

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE

    USE:

    THE THEORY

    OF

    DEPLETION

    discussion question 7). Suppose the initial situation is

    an

    industry facing constant

    costs of c and a choke price ofp see Figure 3.8). The price path t hat satisfies the flow

    and

    terminal conditions along with the stock constraint is

    aa .

    Now, what would

    happen if costs were

    c

    rather than

    c,

    where

    c

    >

    c?

    If he industry tried to follow the

    path aa it would not be maximizing profits. Along the path aa

    '

    ren t will grow faster

    than rate r when costs equal c . Each mine owner then decreases curren t output

    (because rents in the ground exceed returns from extraction), the industry supply

    declines, and the initial price,

    Po,

    rises to Po in Figure 3.8.

    What happens to extraction over time? Ifmine owners produced less outpu t in

    every period when costs are c rather than c, the price pat h would look like df. In this

    situation, the choke price

    pis

    reached when there is still ore remaining

    in

    the ground.

    This cannot be an optimal plan because the terminal condition is not met. What it

    means is that at some point in the extraction path, m ines must begin to increase their

    rate of production, which will cause the mark et price to rise less rapidly than when

    costs were

    c.

    This will ensure that physical depletion occurs atp. Thus, the path dd

    results.

    t

    s important to notice tha t the increase in costs results

    in

    a

    lengthening

    ofthe

    time to depletion. The backstop is reached at T , which exceeds

    T.

    There is an economically intuitive explanation for the effect on the extraction

    and hence the price path when costs c h a n g ~ . If the cost of extraction is higher, in

    present value terms it will benefit each firm to postpone extraction. Iffirms postpone

    incurring the costs, the rents will be larger than if the same path as aa is followed.

    Production is reduced in the early periods and increased in later periods. The present

    value of the mine has fallen due to the increase in costs, but the stock of ore is still

    physically depleted and the terminal condition is met. .

    Rise in Interest Rates

    Suppose that the rate of return on investing

    in

    assets alternative to mineral extraction

    rises. Wh at will be the response

    of

    he mining firms?

    In

    Figure 3.9, suppose the price

    path prior to the increase in the nterest rate

    is

    aa . Ifthe mine operators contInued to

    follow this path, the mines would be earning a lower rate

    of

    return over time

    than

    available elsewhere. The way to avoid this loss is to shift production to the present.

    The mi ne owners will extract more ore in the initial period, thus driving down the

    market price to, say, p (O).

    Thereafter, less ore will be extracted so that the rate

    of

    return

    on

    the remaining

    ore, rises at the now higher interest rate. This means, however, that the time to

    depletion must fall. The extraction path dd will start from a lower initial price than

    did aa and will rise more steeply so that it hits th e choke price at T which is less than

    T. Any other path would not maximize the profits

    of

    he mines, given the new interest

    rate.

    The ntroduction of Taxes

    Suppose the government decided to impose various taxeson the minin g industry.

    What would

    be their effect on the extraction

    and

    price paths,

    and

    the time to deple

    tion? We conside r two types

    of

    axes: a tax on the mineral rent, the difference between

    EXTENSIONS OF THE INDUSTRY MODEL

    ;,

    l i r - - - - - - - - 4 ~ - f - - -

    $

    per ton

    p(O)

    p (O)

    c r - ~ - - - - - - - - - -

    t(O)

    r T

    Time

    ~ i g ~ r e 3 . ~

    The

    c o m p a r a t i v ~

    statics

    o f

    . .

    ,rise n the Interest rate will increase the 0

    an

    I n c r ~ a s e In the Interest ra

    the future (the present value of fut PP?rtumty cost of extracting

    ~ h e present, and the initial price a ~ e

    ~ n t s

    S lower). Extraction s shift

    1

    n

    the ground increase

    in

    value at a hi e smaller amounts of ore rema

    IS s t e e p ~ r than aa . Depletion occu gher ra e th.an ~ e f o r e , so the pat

    exhaustion point ~ n d e r a lower i n t e r ~ ~ t a : a ~ e which S sooner than T

    , price and' marginal cost and a ro alt

    production.

    12

    A rent t a ~ will ha y y tt tax at a constant rate,

    already in existence. There is no no e. ect on the extraction dec

    offset ~ e d ~ c l i n e in the present a l u : ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ th.e rate of x t r a c t i o n ov

    ment

    wIll

    SImply collect som e

    of

    he . e resultmg from the t

    same manner as before the tax ' mmeral rent, and production wi

    T

    . 0 see that this is so, we present the flow . . .

    Imposed. Let a be the tax rate levied 0 . IcondltlOn reqUIred a

    becomes n mmera rents or profits. The n

    -t

    (p(t)

    - c)

    1

    a) =

    1

    - a ) ( p ( ~ - c) (_1_)

    . ' 1 + r

    e c a u ~ e rent m each period is taxedexactl th

    both SIdes of Equation (3 11) Th Y e same, the term (1 -

    h

    . . ere IS no way the mi

    s i mg p oduction. ne operator can

    W ~ l l e a rent tax is said to be

    neutral

    "

    because It does not alter the path th

    or

    nondlstortmg to the

    ?n discovery of new mines. The

    ~ a : ~

    c:nnot be said b o u ~ t h e

    m . d l v l ~ u a l s

    and firms to explore for

    ;ew

    t

    e tax rate,

    t ~ e

    less mcen

    WIth dIfferent taxes levied on their out mmeral

    depOSIts.

    Two id

    m ~ r k e t

    ~ a l u e . The rent tax reduces

    t h e ~ e ~ ~ : : P £ e s e n t

    two a s ~ e t s

    of

    mmeral m the ground _ because th ' : ' rom exploratlOn - t

    dec} , . h " e expected payoff fro d .

    , mes

    WIt

    the tax. We will come back' .

    ..

    m Iscovenn

    and uncertainty in Chapter 5. ' to

    thIS tOPIC

    m our discussion

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    16/24

    7

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE USE: THE THEORY OF DEPLETION

    N ow let us examine the effect

    of

    he imposition of a royalty on the total value of

    mineral extraction. Th e government now taxes the total revenues

    of

    each mining

    firm at, say, rate

    y.

    The introduction of he royalty has an effect analogous to arise in

    the cost of extraction.

    If

    he firm postpones the extraction

    of

    some ore to the future,it

    can then reduce the effect

    of

    he royalty on the present valueof ts rents. To see this,

    we rewrite Equation (3.11) to obtain the flow condition after the royalty.

    1

    1

    - y) p t»

    - c = [ 1

    - y) p t»

    - c] 1 +

    r)

    (3.12)

    Notice that there is no way we can cancel the term 1 -

    y

    from bot h sides of

    Equation (3.12). The royalty reduces the price received by the firm for each unit

    of

    mineral sold and thus, the present value of he mine. If sales are pos tponed, the effect

    of his reduction will be minimized because of he discount factor. The result is a time

    path

    of

    extraction similar to tha t shown

    in

    Figure 3.8; the initial output will fall,

    and

    price will rise. Later

    in

    time, ext raction will rise again,

    and

    price will rise less quickly

    than in the case without a mineral royalty. Again, the time to depletion

    of

    the fixed

    stock

    is

    lengthened. The size

    of

    this effect depends on the magnitude

    of

    costs.

    f

    extraction cost is very small, the distorting effects

    of

    he royalty are relatively small.

    Numer ous other comparative static exercises can be done (see discussion prob

    lem 8). These exercises will help

    in

    understanding the model

    of

    he industry and also

    enable the reader to try applications of he model to some real-world events, such as

    the introduction

    of

    new energy taxes, a fall

    in

    the cost of producing oil from oil shale

    deposits, and so on. We now turn to some further extensions of he industry model

    that make it more compatible with real-world

    o ~ s e r v a t i o n s

    eclining Quality of the Stock

    Suppose the mineral industry finds its stock of ore declining in quality. Deposits of

    poorer quality must be brought on stream as the high-quality reserves are exhausted.

    As

    in the case

    of

    the single mine, quality decline can be viewed as requiring the

    removal of more waste rock per unit of ore extracted to get at the thinner seams of

    metal. Thus the average cost of producing metal increases as more

    of

    he mineral is

    extracted. If each ton has a specific extraction and processing cost associated with it,

    and these costs rise

    as

    more mineral is extracted, the

    flow

    condition

    of

    Equation (3.9)

    remains the same,

    but

    its interpretation is modified.

    For a specific

    ton

    of he mineral, the flow condition requires the rent on tha t ton

    in

    period t to be equal to the discounted rent on that same ton if t were extracted

    in

    period (t

    + 1).

    In period

    t

    this

    ton

    will be the marginal ton extracted, whereas

    in

    .period (t

    + 1) it

    will be the most inframarginal ton extracted. We illustrate the effects

    on

    the industry

    in

    Figure 3.10.

    In Figure 3.10, the rent on the marginal

    ton

    in period t is

    abo

    This same ton

    would obtain the rent

    ofge

    in period t

    +

    1. Distancege must be equal to the amount

    abe1

    +

    r),

    if

    the owner

    of

    the marginal

    ton

    is

    to be

    ndifferent between extracting in

    period

    t

    or period t

    +

    1). All owners of ore inframarginal to the marginal ton earning

    ab at

    t will extract their ore

    at

    that po int simply because their rent

    in

    period t exceeds

    EXTENSIONS OF THE INDUSTRY MODEL

    $

    per

    ton

    o

    q (t) q(t)

    Period t

    D

    $

    per

    ton

    p(t

    + 1)

    e

    o

    q(t

    +

    I)

    Period t + 1

    Figure3 10 The marginal ton extracted

    in

    period t h

    earn rent p(t

    +

    1) _ c

    in

    period t

    +

    1 or dis as rent p e ~

    ~ o n

    of ab or p t) - c

    to extract

    is [p t)

    _ c 1 + )

    = [p(t

    +

    1) ~ a ~ ] c ~ g ~ ~ ~ ~ e r ~ ~ e c o n d l t l o ~

    causing

    q t)

    to

    quality. , . e ~ I s l n g extraction cost per ton

    t ~ e rent they could obtain by waiting until period t

    +

    1). The inf

    q ~ ) h f ? \ e x a ~ p l e earns a rent of a b

    in

    period t. It would earn gei

    w /cfi ;ss h ~ n a b 1

    +

    r). The flow condition for extraction in bo

    sa IS e or t IS ton, and hence the ton is extracted in eri d A

    applies all tons to the left

    of q(t)in

    Figure 3.10.

    pot

    SI

    . . D ~ s t a n c ~ ab is.

    r e ~ t

    per ton. Area cbl s the Ricardian or

    ansmg rom t e vanatIOn m ore quality. The marginal ton of ore in

    e a r ~ s

    a rent equal to

    pet

    +

    1)

    - c .

    Ifthe

    flow condition

    is

    then linked

    ~ e n o d s h the

    m o u n t

    ofo:e be extracted

    at

    each different quality wil

    or

    t

    eac

    t

    d ~ e h n o d The ?nc.e m each period is determined by the agg

    ex rac e

    , t

    US, the pnce

    IS

    endogenous.

    t die ave yet to x a ? I ~ ~ e the terminal condition for the problem

    .0d ep etlon, and e ~ c ~ mlt al q t). Because there are now many grad

    m hustrr we

    A

    must d ~ s t l l ~ g U 1 S h between the possibility of economic

    aus I O ~ ssu?Ie m eIther case that there is a linear demand curve a

    Ph

    If ~ e r e P E y s l ~ a l exhaustion, the output will go to zero in the las

    t epncehltsp WIth

    (T)

    - 0 .

    . q - marginal rent equals average rent on t

    or:. : m ~ ~ e d t i We can then work backward to find the un ique first per

    sa

    IS

    es ow and

    e r m l ~ a l c o n d ~ t i o n

    with complete physical exh

    the fi ~ y : I C a l e ~ h a u s ~ o n wIll occur m any industry ifthe marginal co

    . IS

    ess

    t .an (or equal to) the choke price.

    If,

    however

    quahtles

    WIth

    extractIOn costs m excess

    of

    the choke . I

    h·· ·

    . pnce, econom

    o c c u ~ s n t I s l t u a t I O n ~ the mming sequence ends when the choke p

    marginal cost of extractIOn. There will be an ore grade at whl'ch m

    fin 1 t' . mm

    a quan Ity extracted from all mmes is that which yieldsp- - c

    =

    0 A

    backward fi th . .

    d

    ..

    . rom

    IS

    quantIty to find the initial output level that sat

    con

    ItIOn

    m each penod.

  • 8/17/2019 HartwickOlewiler1986 TOC Ch3

    17/24

    72

    NONRENEWABLE RESOURCE USE: THE THEORY OF DEPLETION

    Deposits

    of

    Distinct and Differing Quality .

    N owwe examine the case where each deposit has ore of a unif0rD?-

    q ~ a l i t y

    but i f f e ~ s

    in quality from other deposits. What is an optimal plan for e x p l O 1 t a t ~ o n of ore m thIS

    case? We can tr eat ore qual ity as signifying different costs

    of

    extractIOn process

    ing. These costs

    of

    extraction could be due to ore grade

    and s e ~ m

    t h I c k ~ e s s

    as

    discussed earlier, or simply to the fact that deposits are o ~ a t e d ~ t ~ I f f e ~ ; n t d ~ s t ~ n c e s

    from a central market. Trans porta tion costs give the deposIts a dIstmct quah ty ; the

    metal is still of uniform quality. .

    Consider an example

    of

    two deposits of different quality within a competlt.Ive

    industry. Each deposit is within itself of uniform quality.

    e ~ o s i t

    1 has. extractIOn

    costs

    of

    c and

    an

    initial stockof eserves equal to 8

    1

    tons. DepOSIt 2 has umt costs of C

    2

    and

    rese;ves equal to 8

    2

    ,

    As

    long as the demand curve remains s ~ a t i o . n a r y only the

    low-cost deposit will be exploited initially. Why? Suppose deposl.t

    lIS

    the low-c?st

    deposit. Its extraction costs are shown in Figure 3: 11 as c

    i

    . ExtractIOn

    fr0D?-

    deposIt 1

    commences at T where the initial rent earned IS the amount abo DepOSIt 2 clearly

    cannot come on t r e a m at

    Tl because

    at

    price

    PI

    it will incur a substantial loss. Its

    extraction costs of C2 greatly exceed the initial price.

    How is this initial price set? Why is n't the initial price high enough to allow

    b?th

    deposits to o p ~ r a t e ? One way to see why the initial price is ~ e s s than the extractI?n

    costs of he high-cost deposit is to work backward from the tIme when b oth ~ p o ~ ~ s

    are exhausted - that is,

    we

    use the terminal condition. As long as the choke pnceP

    S

    greater than C2, we know that physical exhaustion must

    c c u r .

    At T, q(T) = 0. The

    rent at

    T

    would be equal to

    p

    -

    C

    I

    for deposit 1 and

    P - C

    2

    for deposIt 2 If both

    extracted their last tpn of ore

    at

    this point. Deposit 1 s rent greatly exceeds that of

    a

    p

    I

    I

    g per ton

    I

    I

    I

    I

    I

    I

    I

    P2

    ~ - - - - - - - - j l d

    I

    2

    I

    I

    I

    I

    I

    I

    ----1

    b

     

    Pi

    b

    I

    T

    Time

    Figure

    3 11 The

    low-cost deposit is extracted

    b e t w e ~ ~ T

    and T ·

    Upon

    exhaustion

    the

    second

    deposit is

    worked

    until

    it

    is exhausted

    at time

    T

    P S the

    cost of

    the

    backstop.

    Rents

    rise over each phase at the rate of interest.

    EXTENSIONS

    OF

    THE INDUSTRY MODEL

    deposit 2. Can we then arrange extraction in each period prior to T

    condition

    is

    met for each deposit? The answer

    is

    no

    if

    each

    simultaneouslyand yes if they operate sequentially.

    Consider simultaneous extraction. T he price

    in

    each period m

    for each deposit if both are to sell any metal. There is then no wa

    condition can be met for both firms. Working backward from

    T,.

    the

    . cannot simultaneously be the same for each deposit with different

    and the same market price. In particular, if a path such as a C is fo

    deposit 1 will not be falling fast enough from T. Only deposit 2 can

    satisfy the flow condition.

    If here is sequential extraction, then for each deposit both th

    and

    terminal condition will be met, along with physical exhaustion

    ward from T where the choke price is reached, deposit 2 will be ex

    interval

    T2

    to T. Tis defined by the choke r i c e ~

    T2

    is defined by the in

    2 can earn to satisfy the flow condition for each period and exhaust

    rent for deposit 2 the amount

    cd,

    will be that which comp ounded a

    terminal rent a d as the ore body is depleted.

    T2

    is also the time

    physically exhausts its reserves.

    It will not pay the owners

    of

    deposit 1 to extract once the price

    because they know that th en deposit 2 can begin extraction. Ifboth

    extract simultaneously, the market price would not rise fast enou

    satisfy the flow condition,