Risk Rating Article 2004

  • Upload
    ekaljc

  • View
    244

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    1/56

    Les Cahiers du CREF ISSN: 1707-410X

    The Ordered Qualitative Model forCredit Rating Transitions

    Dingan FengChristian GourirouxJoann Jasiak

    CREF 04-05

    April 2004

    Tous droits rservs pour tous les pays. Toute traduction et toute reproduction sous quelque forme que ce soit est interdite.

    Les textes publis dans la srie Les Cahiers du CREF de HEC Montral n'engagent que la responsabilit de leurs auteurs. La

    publication de cette srie de rapports de recherche bnficie d'une subvention du programme de l'Initiative de la nouvelle

    conomie (INE) du Conseil de recherches en sciences humaines du Canada (CRSH).

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    2/56

    The Ordered Qualitative Model for Credit RatingTransitions

    Dingan Feng

    Post Doctoral Student

    CREF and York University

    Department of Economics

    4700 Keele Street

    Toronto, Ontario M3J 1P3

    E-Mail:[email protected]

    Christian Gouriroux

    Professor

    CREF, CREST, CEPREMAP

    and University of Toronto

    15, boulevard Gabriel Pri

    92245 Malakoff

    E-Mail: [email protected]

    Joann Jasiak

    Professor

    CREF and York University

    Department of Economics

    4700 Keele Street

    Toronto, Ontario M3J 1P3

    E-Mail:[email protected]

    April 2004

    Les Cahiers du CREF

    CREF 04-05

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    3/56

    Les Cahiers du CREF CREF 04-05

    The Ordered Qualitative Model for Credit Rating Transitions

    Abstract

    The dynamic analysis of corporate credit ratings is needed for predicting therisk included in a credit portfolio at different horizons. In this paper, we presentthe estimation of an ordered probit model with factors for the migrationprobabilities, with its application to aggregate data regularly reported byStandard & Poor's.

    Keywords: Credit Rating, Migration

    JEL : C23, C35, G11

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    4/56

    1 Introduction

    Credit ratings for firms and bond issuing are regularly reported by specialized rating agencies such

    as Moodys, Standard &Poors and Fitch. A credit rating provides a measure of risk quality, and

    is a basic tool for risk management. This paper is concerned by the dynamic analysis of ratings

    for a homogenous population of firms (bonds). The analysis is based on an ordered qualitative

    model explaining how the transition probabilities between credit rating categories depend on some

    underlying unobservable factors. In Section 2, we present the deterministic and stochastic ordered

    probit specifications for the transition probabilities. In particular we explain why it is necessary to

    introduce stochastic transition to define and study joint migration, which arises when several firms

    are jointly down- or up-graded. Statistical inference is discussed in Section 3, for both determin-

    istic and stochastic specifications. We explain how the panel data on ratings can be aggregated

    per year without any loss of information. This possibility of aggregation is used to define a two

    step estimation approach for the nonlinear latent factor model of transition. In the first step an

    approximated latent factor model is estimated from the aggregate observed transition frequencies.

    Then this first step estimator is used as a starting value before applying a (more efficient) simulated

    maximum likelihood approach.

    The methodology is applied to the aggregate transition frequencies regularly reported by Stan-

    dard & Poors, in Section 4. We first explain how to correct for missing data (the so-called not

    rated companies). Then the deterministic ordered qualitative model is estimated independently for

    each year. This allows to obtain time dependent risk summaries, such as average risk, and risk

    volatility per rating class. Different tests are performed on this basic specification to indicate

    which summaries can be assumed time independent. Then the approach is extended to stochastic

    models featuring either serial independence between transition, or serial dependence by means of

    a small number of factors. The estimated stochastic migration model is used in Section 5 to predict

    future ratings. Section 6 concludes.

    1

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    5/56

    2 Specification of migration dynamics

    The aim of migration (or transition) models is to analyze the credit rating histories of several firms.

    The basic models arise as specifications of the transition matrix, which consists of the probabilities

    of migration from one rating category to another rating category for a given firm in a given period.

    According to the selected specification, the transition matrix can be time independent (time homo-

    geneity assumption), or can vary in time in either a deterministic (heterogeneity assumption), or a

    stochastic way (stochastic transition model). In this section, we present the approach based on the

    ordered qualitative dependent variable models.

    The credit rating categories are denoted by

    Thus the individual histo-

    ries (

    correspond to qualitative processes with state space

    .

    2.1 Deterministic models

    2.1.1 Dependence assumption

    The basic simple specification is obtained under the following assumptions,

    Assumption A1: The individual histories (

    are independent,

    identically distributed;

    Assumption A2: Any individual history satisfies the Markov condition, that is the most recent

    individual rating summarizes efficiently the whole individual history.

    Under Assumptions A1, A2, the joint dynamics of rating histories of all firms is characterized

    by the sequence of transition matrices

    . The matrix

    is a

    matrix. Its

    elements provide the transition probabilities from a rating

    to another rating

    between dates

    and

    ,

    (1)

    The transition probabilities are the same for different individuals, which is the homogeneity as-

    2

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    6/56

    sumption accross the population of firms . They are non-negative and sum up to one by column.

    When the Markov process is time heterogenous [resp. time homogenous], the transition probabili-

    ties depend on [resp. do not depend on ].

    2.1.2 The ordered qualitative model

    It can be useful to constrain the transition matrices in order to diminish the number of parameters

    to be estimated [curse of dimensionality], and to robustify the results. A structural model for

    transition matrices is based on the fact that the individual qualitative ratings are usually determined

    from an underlying continuous score. More precisely, it is common to assign a continuous grade

    (or score) , which is an increasing function of estimated default probability, to each firm at every

    date. Let us denote

    the value of the score. The qualitative rating is obtained by discretizing the

    score values. More precisely, let us introduce a partition

    of admissible values

    of the score. Then the observed rating is defined by,

    if and only if

    (2)

    where by convention,

    and

    . The relation (2) expresses the link between the

    observable endogenous variable

    and the score

    , which is generally not publicly diffused

    (when it exists), and has to be considered as a latent variable.

    Then the model is completed by specifying the (conditional) distribution of the quantitative

    score. In the ordered polytomous model, the underlying scores are such that,

    Assumption A1 : The individual score histories are independent, identically distributed;

    Assumption A2 : The conditional distribution of

    given the lagged score values depends

    on the past through the most recent qualitative rating only. This distribution is such that:

    if

    (3)

    see Gagliardini, and Gourieroux(2003)a for a discussion of the homogeneity assumption.

    3

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    7/56

    where

    are i.i.d. variables with identical cumulative density function (cdf) . Thus the

    conditional mean and variance depend on the current rating.

    The expressions of transition probabilities follow directly from Assumptions A1, A2. We get,

    or:

    (4)

    For example,

    is the probability of default of a firm rated

    ;

    similarly

    is the probability of migration to the highest category 1, or AAA.

    The parameters

    are identifiable up to some linear

    affine transformation on and a linear transformation on . Under identification restriction,

    different transition probabilities now depend on a smaller number of parameters equal

    to .

    The ordered probit model is obtained when the error variable

    is standard normal, and the

    cdf is replaced by the cdf of the standard normal. This type of ordered probit model is frequently

    encountered in both the applied and theoretical literature [see e.g. Gupton, Finger, Bhatia (1997),

    Nickell, Perraudin, Varotto (2000), Bangia, Diebold, Kronimus, Schlagen, Schuermann(2002),

    Albanese et alii. (2003)a].

    Remark 1: In the application to firm rating, one of the states corresponds to default and is by

    definition an absorbing state. If this state has index , then we have:

    if

    otherwise

    or implicitly

    . In this framework the (non degenerate) ordered qualitative model applies

    to the remaining columns of the transition matrix.

    It is usually called the asset value model by reference to Merton(1974). However the latent variable

    does not

    necessarily admit an interpretation as a difference between liabilities and asset values as in Mertons model.

    4

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    8/56

    2.2 Stochastic transition models

    The deterministic models can be extended to allow for stochastic transition matrices. In this re-

    spect, they extend the stochastic intensity model, largely used for modeling default [see e.g. Lando

    (1998), Duffie and Singleton (1999)]. The advantage of specifying stochastic transition matrices

    is twofold. First the time heterogeneous deterministic Markov chain can be used for prediction

    purpose, only if the dynamics of transition matrices is clearly defined . Thus it is necessary to

    introduce such a stochastic dynamics, which will involve a small number of underlying factors for

    tractability and robustness purposes. Second the migration correlations, which measure the joint

    up- or down-grades of firms, can be defined in the stochastic framework only [see e.g. Gagliardini

    and Gourieroux (2003)a,b] . In Section 2.2.1, we describe a specification with i.i.d. transition

    matrices. The factor ordered qualitative model is discussed in Section 2.2.2.

    2.2.1 I.I.D. transition matrices

    A simple specification is obtained when the dated transition matrices (

    ) are as-

    sumed independent, identically distributed (i.i.d.). Let us explain how the assumption of stochastic

    transition modifies the probabilistic properties of the rating histories.

    Under the deterministic model considered in Section 2.1:

    i) The individual histories are independent (Assumption A.1),

    ii) Any individual history satisfies a Markov process, with given time dependent parametric

    transitions.

    In particular, the prediction of future states at all horizons is easy to perform. Let us define the

    vector of state indicators:

    (5)

    where :

    Contrary to a usual belief, The method of estimation (of joint credit quality co-movements) has the advantage

    that it does not make assumption on the underlying process (Gupton et alii.(1997)), the migration correlations and

    their estimation can only be considered within a precise specification of default.

    5

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    9/56

    if firm is in state at date

    otherwise

    The knowledge of rating histories

    is equivalent to the knowledge of indicator histories.

    Moreover the prediction of

    performed at date is simply:

    E

    (6)

    Let us now assume that the transition matrices are iid and unobserved. Then:

    i) The individual histories become dependent.

    Indeed let us consider the covariance between two firm ratings,

    , when their pre-

    vious ratings are known. By the covariance decomposition equation, we get:

    cov

    E cov

    cov E

    E

    cov

    Therefore,

    cov

    cov

    These covariances are generally different from zero. For instance, let us assume current identical

    ratings , and consider joint up-grades by one bucket: . We get:

    cov

    var

    which is strictly positive due to the stochastic assumption on the transition matrix. This com-

    putation shows that stochastic transition matrices are introduced to define non-zero cross-sectional

    correlations.

    ii) Any individual history is a homogeneous Markov process.

    6

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    10/56

    Indeed, from the prediction formula (6) and the iterated expectation theorem, it follows that:

    E

    E

    E

    E

    E

    E

    by the i.i.d. assumption on transition matrices.

    Thus the rating history of a given individual satisfies a Markov property with a time indepen-

    dent transition matrix, equal to the expected stochastic transition:

    E

    (7)

    iii) Joint analysis of two firms histories.

    The results given above can be extended to a joint analysis of rating histories of two firms

    and

    , say. Typically the joint transition probabilities are given by:

    E

    E

    The matrix is a matrix of all joint transition probabilities. In general this matrix

    is different from the matrix with elements

    as a consequence of migration correlation.

    2.2.2 Factor ordered qualitative model

    The stochastic transition model with iid transition matrices is simple to apply to credit analysis,

    since, as mentioned above, it provides homogenous Markov rating histories. Equivalently, in fi-

    nancial term, it provides a flat term structure of migration correlations and thus flat term structures

    of spreads of interest rates.

    For a more flexible term structure specification, it is necessary to introduce serial dependence

    between the transition matrices. This can be done in the ordered qualitative model by writing the

    time dependent parameters

    as functions of (unobservable) dynamic factors (

    ).

    7

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    11/56

    i) For instance, let us assume that

    , independent of ,

    , independent of , and

    consider a linear factorial representation for the latent means:

    (8)

    where the factors satisfy a Gaussian Vector Autoregressive (VAR) model:

    (9)

    and the error terms are iid standard normal vectors

    .

    By introducing the factor representation (4)-(8)-(9), the parameters of time dependent

    latent means are replaced by parameters. Note that some sensitivity

    coefficients can be close to zero in practice. This can arise when one factor,

    , say, is driving

    the extreme risks. Thus the coefficient corresponding to this factor and to the high ratings will be

    small. It can be easily checked that in the factor ordered qualitative model the rating histories are

    no longer Markov processes. Each current rating is influenced by all past ratings, including also

    the ratings of other firms which provide information on the (unobservable) past factor values.

    In practice, the factors can correspond to some observable variables or be considered as un-

    observables. The first approach has been followed for instance by Bangia et alii (2002), who

    consider a single factor model and select the indicator of recession-expansion regularly reported

    by the NBER as the factor. A similar approach has also been implemented by Nickell, Perraudin

    and Varotto (2000) with several individual explanatory variables and a time dependent variable

    related to business cycle, which is based on the GDP growth rate by country. They distinguish if

    the country growth rate is in upper, middle or lower third of growth rate recorded in the sample

    period. The approach with observable factors is simple to implement from the statistical point of

    view, since we get a standard ordered probit regression model. However it can lead to misspecifi-

    Since the factors are defined up to a linear invertible transformation, it is always possible to fix the covariance

    matrix of the error term at identity.

    8

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    12/56

    cation if the factor variable is not well selected. For instance, the importance of the U.S. business

    cycle can be questioned on a set of firms, which includes almost 30% of foreign firms, and can

    gather industrial sectors with different cycles. Moreover as mentioned earlier a model with ob-

    servable factor can not handle efficiently the migration correlation feature and is difficult to use

    for prediction purpose. Indeed it is usually more difficult to predict the future business cycles than

    directly the migrations.

    In a first step, it is preferable to search for factors intrinsic to the credit problem, to try to

    reconstitute the factors (filtering step) and then possibly to interpret them ex-post as a function of

    observed macro-variables.

    3 Statistical inference

    The parameters of interest can be estimated by exact or approximated maximum likelihood (ML)

    for all models introduced above.

    3.1 Deterministic transition matrices

    When the transition matrices are deterministic and parameterized by , the -likelihood function

    is:

    (10)

    where

    denotes the number of firms which migrates from to between and .

    In particular, the expression of the -likelihood function shows that the set of counts (

    )

    provide a sufficient statistic for parameters . This is a consequence of the cross-sectional homo-

    geneity hypothesis.

    3.1.1 Unconstrained model

    Let us assume that the different transition matrices

    are unconstrained, except the positivity and

    unit mass restrictions. Then the parameter is

    ,

    9

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    13/56

    and satisfies the constraints:

    The unconstrained ML estimator of the transition matrices is given by :

    (11)

    where

    denotes the number of firms in grade

    at the beginning of period

    . The uncon-

    strained estimator corresponds to the transition frequencies for date t.

    3.1.2 Constrained model

    It is useful to introduce the transition frequencies in the expression of the

    -likelihood function.

    We get :

    Both the transition frequencies

    and the sample structure per grade (

    ) are

    available aggregate information, and then the likelihood estimator can be used (if

    is identifiable).

    The fact that the structure per grade is now required is due to the constraints between transition

    matrices of different dates by means of the common parameters

    . Indeed the population of firms,

    that are their size and structure per grade, change with time. The counts

    are used to weight in

    an appropriate way the information of the different dates . The objective criterion involves a mea-

    sure

    for the discrepancy between sample and theoretical transition probabilities,

    called information criterion. It should seem natural to replace this measure by a chi-square mea-

    sure

    say. However the chi-square criterion has to be used with care; indeed,

    whereas the number of firms is large, the major part of sample frequencies observed in practice are

    see De Servigny, Renault (2002) for a discussion of weighting in transition models.

    10

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    14/56

    equal to zero. In this situation in which the chi-square approximation (which is based on central

    limit theorem) is not very accurate.

    3.2 Stochastic transition matrices

    The maximum likelihood approach is easily extended to stochastic transition models. Let us con-

    sider for the discussion a factor model, where the transition probabilities depend on a (multivariate)

    factor value

    :

    say (12)

    and the factor satisfies a Gaussian VAR model:

    (13)

    where the errors

    are i.i.d. standard normal. The parameters to be estimated are (i) the

    parameters defining the transition probabilities, (ii) the parameter which characterizes the

    factor dynamics. We assume that these parameters are identifiable. They are called micro-and

    macro-parameters, respectively, in the general approach of error-in-factor model developped in

    Gourieroux-Monfort (2004).

    3.2.1 Simulated maximum likelihood

    If both rating and factor histories were observed, the likelihood function would be:

    (14)

    When the factors are not observed, the distribution has to be integrated with respect to factor

    values

    . We get a likelihood function based on the rating histories only:

    11

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    15/56

    where denotes the joint distribution of the factor values

    . Thus the log-likelihood:

    involves a multivariate integral with a dimension equal to , which can be very large. This

    integral can not be computed easily and is replaced in practice by an approximation computed by

    simulation to get the so-called simulated likelihood [see e.g. Gourieroux and Monfort (1995) for a

    survey].

    The simulated maximum likelihood (SML) estimator is defined as:

    A

    A

    A A

    where the simulated factor values are computed recursively by:

    (15)

    with the initial condition

    , and the errors

    independently drawn in the standard

    normal. The initial condition is fixed at a past date to ensure that some stationary behaviour of the

    factor is reached for the period of interest starting at .

    3.2.2 Approximated linear factor model

    The SML approach can be rather time consuming and it is useful to also present an estimation

    method providing consistent results, even if they are partly subefficient. This first step estimation

    will be used for the preliminary analysis of the stochastic migration model, in particular for deter-

    mining the number of factors and constraining their dynamics. In a second step, it will be used as

    initial value of the numerical algorithm used to maximize the simulated likelihood function. Let us

    consider the factor ordered qualitative model where the Gaussian autoregressive factors are driving

    the latent means [see equations (4)-(8)-(9)]. If the number of firms per rating class, that are

    , are

    12

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    16/56

    sufficiently large, the estimators

    of the latent means, computed per year, will be close to the

    true latent means. Thus we can write:

    (16)

    where the errors (

    ) are Gaussian . Thus we get approximately a Gaussian linear factor

    model, which can be analyzed in the usual way by means of the Kalman filter. It provides estimates

    of parameters A and var , but also approximated factor value (smoothing). It is proved

    in Gourieroux, Monfort (2004) that these approximations are rather accurate. Typically if both

    the time dimension and the cross-sectional dimension tend to infinity the estimators and the

    smoothed values are consistent. Moreover if

    tend to zero, the approximated estimator of

    the macro-parameter are

    consistent and efficient. If tend to zero the estimator of the

    microparameter is

    - consistent and the error on the smoothing value is of order .

    4 Application

    The deterministic and stochastic ordered qualitative transition models will be estimated from the

    aggregate data regularly reported by Standard & Poors [ See Brady,Bos(2002), Brady, Vazza, Bos

    (2003)]. In the first section, we describe the data set and explain how to correct the bias for missing

    data on not rated companies. In Section 4.2, the deterministic models are estimated independently

    for each year. This allows to derive the estimated cutting points

    , as well

    as the estimated mean

    and variances

    per rating category

    and to observe how they vary in time. Different tests are performed to check for the time stability

    of the parameters. In Section 4.3, we focus on the model with time independent cutting points:

    independent of , and on the time series properties of the conditional mean and variance

    They can be assumed Gaussian by the Central Limit Theorem applied to the estimator

    .

    13

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    17/56

    as a preliminary step before estimating an i.i.d. stochastic transition model in Section 4.4 and a

    stochastic ordered qualitative transition model in Section 4.5.

    4.1 Data set

    The data set used in this paper has been obtained from Rating Performance 2002 provided by

    Standard & Poors, which is free down-loadable at www.standardandpoors.com. The data con-

    sists of yearly transition matrices from year 1981 to year 2002, reported in [Table 15: Static Pool

    One-Year Transition Matrices in Standard & Poors (2003)], [see also Brady, Vazza and Bos

    (2003)]. According to S&P rating system, there are

    rating grades. They are AAA,AA, A,

    BBB, BB, B, CCC and D from lowest risk to highest risk up to default state D [for

    the definition of each rating and the correlation with other rating systems, refer to Foulcher et alii.

    (2003)]. Since the published ratings focus on individual bond issuers, S&P convert their bond

    rating to issuer ratings by considering the implied long-term senior unsecured rating [see Bangia

    et alii (2002)] . Here for convenience, we use one-digital number 1,2, up to 8 for the rating

    grades, and for example, 1 is for the highest rating category AAA, 8 for default D. The

    number of states is . Therefore we have the following scheme:

    Table 1: Scheme 1

    R.C

    AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC D

    C.P

    Note: R.C. and C.P. stand for Rating category and cutting point respectively.

    The yearly transition matrix displays all rating movements during one year period and account

    for missing data . A typical example of transition matrix is given in Table 2 and corresponds to

    year 1997.

    Similarly Nickell, Perraudin and Varotto (2000) considered long term corporate and sovereign bond ratings on the

    Moodys data base.

    14

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    18/56

    Table 2: Transition matrix of year 1997

    Issuers

    1 199 94.47 4.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.51

    2 586 0.85 91.30 2.90 0.85 0.00 0.34 0.00 0.00 3.75

    3 1161 0.00 1.64 89.15 3.70 0.17 0.43 0.00 0.00 4.91

    4 846 0.00 0.35 3.66 86.29 2.72 0.71 0.12 0.35 5.79

    5 557 0.00 0.00 0.18 8.62 76.12 4.67 0.00 0.18 10.23

    6 479 0.00 0.00 0.63 0.42 7.10 74.53 2.51 3.34 11.48

    7 28 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 14.29 53.57 10.71 21.43

    This table has columns and rows. The rows represent the rating category at the beginning

    of year 1997. For example, the first row refers to the rating category 1, or AAA, the last row

    refers to the rating level 7, or CCC. The 8 or D is excluded because once the firm defaults,

    it remains in default forever. The columns contain different information. The first column, named

    Issuers, provides the numbers of long-term rated issuers on 12:01 a.m. January 1, 1997 per

    rating, that is the structure per rating

    at the beginning of the period . The columns 2 to 9

    correspond to rating levels 1, to 8 at the end of year 1997. The last column, 9 corresponds

    to the alternative N.R., which means not rated. It refers to issuers which are not rated at the

    end of year, but were rated at the beginning of the year. As pointed out by Brady, Vazza and Bos,

    (2003), Ratings are withdrawn when an entitys entire debt is paid off or when the program or

    programs rated are terminated and the relevant debt extinguished. They may also occur as a result

    of mergers and acquisitions. Others are withdrawn because of a lack of cooperation. From the

    statistical point of view, the rating cannot be assigned due to a lack of information concerning the

    balance sheet of firms. Thus they correspond to missing data. The proportions of missing data

    in the available data bases from S&P and Moodys are rather high (between 10% and 20%). Let

    us now discuss more precisely the data in columns 1 to 9. They provide the observed transition

    frequencies for year 1997, including the N.R. alternative. For example, the third row shows that

    See Brady Vazza and Bos, (2003) for the precise definition of the so-called static pool.

    15

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    19/56

    out of 1161 firms rated A at the beginning of the year 1997: no one were rated as AAA at

    the end of the year 1997; 1.64% were upgraded to AA; 89.15% stayed in the same category; the

    proportion downrated to BBB, BB,B were 3.7%, 0.17% and 0.12%, respectively. The last

    number, 4.91%, stands for the proportion of firms which were not rated.

    In order to describe the rating migration, a complete rating migration structure is required. This

    is not the case with the matrix given in Table 2, since the transition probabilities for the companies

    not rated at the beginning of the year are not provided. Then two approaches can be followed:

    i) we can include the alternative N.R. in the state space; or

    ii) just consider the rating alternatives 1 to 8, that are AAA to D.

    However the first approach requires including additional row for companies, which are not

    rated at the beginning of 1997. Generally this information is not provided by the rating companies,

    likely for confidentiality reasons. Indeed it could be used to find out the evolution of the population

    of firms, which ask to be rated by the rating agency, and also its structure with respect to risk

    quality. Because the first possibility requires additional information about firms, which is not

    easily available, we will follow the second option, which excludes the N.R. alternative from

    the transition matrix, as in [Foulcher et. al. (2003)]. For this purpose, the incomplete transition

    matrix given by S&P is normalized, by assigning proportionally the N.R. firms among the other

    categories (see below) . We get the so-called N.R.-adjusted transition matrix of year 1997 given

    in Table 3 (as above, the row 8 or D is not reported).

    Let us consider the third row of this matrix for example. The transition frequency from A

    to AA is 1.72%, which is computed as . The N.R.-adjusted transition

    matrices are used in the analysis below as measures of the unconstrained transition frequencies

    .

    The matrix defined in Table 3 is typical of an observed rating transition matrix. The frequen-

    cies are close to one on the diagonal, which shows that the changes of categories are not very

    This assignment of NR companies assumes no selection bias.

    16

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    20/56

    Table 3: N.R. adjusted transition matrix of year 1997

    1 95.92 4.08 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

    2 0.88 94.87 3.01 0.88 0.00 0.35 0.00 0.00

    3 0.00 1.72 93.75 3.89 0.18 0.45 0.00 0.00

    4 0.00 0.37 3.89 91.60 2.89 0.75 0.13 0.37

    5 0.00 0.00 0.20 9.60 84.79 5.20 0.00 0.20

    6 0.00 0.00 0.71 0.47 8.02 84.19 2.84 3.77

    7 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 18.19 68.18 13.63

    frequent. The transition frequencies on the two diagonals below and above the main diagonal are

    also significant, while the other ones are generally equal to zero. Indeed the changes of categories

    (down- or up-grades) are at most by one bucket. In one year it takes some time to get a significant

    change for more than one bucket. It happens mainly to firms, close to a failure which has not

    been predicted by the rating agency; then the agency will quickly perform several down-grades to

    correct for its prediction error. This effect can be viewed at the bottom of Table 3. We also observe

    more heterogeneity in low ratings than in high ratings.

    4.2 Estimation of the deterministic ordered qualitative model

    In the first step, we consider the estimation of the deterministic ordered qualitative model from

    the NR adjusted transition matrices computed from S&P data set. The estimation is performed

    separately for each year, which provides approximation of the cutting points

    , of the latent

    means

    and latent standard errors

    ,

    Different estimation methods have been considered:

    1) The maximum likelihood approach, for which the objective function corresponds to the

    information criterion:

    for model identification and 1 corresponds to the highest rating AAA.

    17

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    21/56

    2) The chi-square type ( ) criterion, where only sufficiently large observed transition proba-

    bilities are taken into account. The criterion is:

    where

    denotes the indicator function with value , if

    , value , otherwise. The

    threshold has been fixed to and .

    The three estimation procedures provide similar results, except for the beginning of the period

    . The estimated values of the different parameters for the maximum likelihood ap-

    proach are displayed in Table 16, Table 17 and Table 18 in the appendix and the goodness of fit

    measure,

    is computed per year and reported in Table 4.

    Table 4: Goodness of fit by ML

    Year

    0.005 0.017 0.023 0.021 0.037 0.038 0.017 0.022

    Year 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995

    0.024 0.027 0.028 0.032 0.050 0.006 0.008

    Year 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002

    0.016 0.007 0.099 0.013 0.016 0.025 0.032

    The -goodness of fit statistics seems stable in time, but its value is difficult to interpret,

    since the measure depends on the accuracy of transition probabilities close to zero and transition

    probabilities close to .

    The chi-square measure is not weighted by the inverse of the frequencies to avoid the problem of null observed

    frequencies (see Table 3).

    18

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    22/56

    Let us now discuss more carefully the estimated parameters. By definition the cutting points

    are in increasing order. Moreover, for a firm in category (AAA) the probability to be downrated

    to or less is equal to

    . Since these probabilities are small, we expect

    positive cutting points, which are observed in Table 16. Similarly we expect increasing positive

    values for the mean per category, since the risk increases with and the mean has been fixed to

    zero for the highest category [See Table 17]. Concerning the variances, the highest ones are for

    category B, AAA (by convention,

    ), AA and BB.

    The dynamics of the estimated parameters can be visualized by reporting their values as func-

    tion of time. These time series are given in Figures 1.a, 1.b, 1.c. It has to be interpreted with

    caution, since it can concern ratios of different parameters due to identification constraints.

    For years , the estimates are more erratic. It seems that this is not caused by a

    change in the risk on corporates, but rather by different data collecting techniques. Indeed the

    quality of data has improved in recent years. In particular, the data base for the initial years 1981-

    1987 is currently under revision. This explains for instance the big differences between transition

    matrices reported by S&P in 2002 and 2003 for these years 1981-1987. Moreover the structure

    of the population of firms by geography (North America, Western Europe, Asia) and by industry

    (Manufacturing, Utilities, Financial Institute,...) has been more stable after 1990, as shown in

    [Bangia et alii (2002) Figure 5, or in Nickell et alii (2000) for Moodys data set], Since we are

    interested in time varying factor model, a use of the data base including the first years, during

    which the proportions of foreign firms and of non manufacturing firms increase will provide a first

    factor measuring the change of structure of the data base instead of measuring the risk fundamental.

    For both reasons, in the sequel, we keep only the reliable data from 1990 to 2002.

    4.3 Test of the ordered probit model

    In Section 4.2 the deterministic ordered probit model has been estimated per year without in-

    tertemporal constraints on the parameters. However it is important to check if some parameters

    19

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    23/56

    can be assumed constant in the period 1990-2002 before introducing stochastic factors. Three con-

    strained estimation procedures of the model for the whole sampling period 1990-2002 have been

    performed with i) constant cutting points, ii) constant cutting points and constant latent variances

    and iii) constant cutting points and constant latent means. We provide in Table 19 in the appendix

    the -goodness of fit measures for the different years and constraints. These -measures are

    small, that is the constrained model provides good fit, when either the cutting points, or the latent

    variances are constrained to be constant. In the sequel, we consider the model with time invari-

    ant cutting points, that is we assume that S&P does not modify the definition of the rating levels

    in the different years. Under this restriction, the estimated latent means and stan-

    dard deviations (squared root of variance) are given in Figure 2 and Figure 3 in the appendix for

    the period :

    As expected, the estimated latent means are in the right order: the higher the rating, the smaller

    are the mean and the default probability (see Figure 2). However, contrary to what can be expected,

    a similar ordering does not appear for the latent variance. This can be explained in two ways. First,

    this is a consequence of the data themselves. When we consider the probit transformation on the

    probabilities to stay in the same state

    , and compute their historical variance,

    we get the values: 0.21 for AAA, 0.15 for AA, 0.12 for A, 0.08 for BBB, 0.10 for BB, 0.09

    for B and 0.25 for CCC. Thus the fact that the heterogeneity decreases when the rating category

    improves is not observed. If the heterogeneity is the largest for CCC, we also observe rather large

    values for AAA and AA. Second, the latent variances are more difficult to estimate than the latent

    means. They require more observations and are very sensitive to the numerical computation of

    the cumulative density function (cdf) of the standard normal in the tails for example. This lack of

    robustness will be diminished in the sequel by constraining the latent variances ( and the cutting

    points) to be time independent. Finally the latent means seem less stable than the latent variances,

    especially for the risky classes. This is an incentive for introducing the factors through the latent

    means in a first step. Finally the standardized cutting points

    , where

    is the

    20

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    24/56

    cdf of the standard normal are provided in Table 5. They give the limiting migration probabilities

    to categories worse than , for a firm rated 1, or AAA, and are compatible with the observed

    probabilities (see the first row of Table 3).

    Table 5: Standardized cutting points

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7

    0.051 2.12e-10 3.36e-11 7.30e-14 1.91e-17 1.35e-35 5.94e-38

    4.4 Stochastic model with iid transition matrices

    Let us now consider a stochastic specification of the dated transition matrices. Under the iid as-

    sumption, we have seen in Section 2.2.1 that any individual rating history defines a Markov process

    with transition matrix:

    E

    This matrix can be estimated by averaging the observed frequencies over time:

    (17)

    The estimated value of

    is given below:

    Table 6: Estimated aggregate transition matrix

    1 94.88 5.12 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

    2 0.00 91.64 6.14 2.21 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

    3 0.00 0.00 94.64 5.36 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

    4 0.00 0.39 4.66 87.98 6.98 0.00 0.00 0.00

    5 0.00 0.00 0.01 6.42 82.94 10.64 0.00 0.00

    6 0.00 0.12 0.11 1.03 5.06 82.66 4.62 6.39

    7 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 10.05 61.12 28.83

    21

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    25/56

    An idea of the dynamics of the associated chain is provided by the spectral decomposition of

    the matrix. The estimated eigenvalues and eigenvectors are given in Table 7.

    Table 7: Eigenvalues and eigenvectors of the aggregate estimated transition matrix

    Values 1.000 0.988 0.949 0.920-0.005i 0.920+0.005i 0.844 0.749 0.590

    V 1.000 0.942 1.000 -6.890-4.714i -6.890+4.714i -0.058 -0.004 0.000

    E 1.000 0.717 0.000 3.430+3.381i 3.430-3.381i 0.119 0.015 0.001

    C 1.000 0.652 0.000 0.580-0.111i 0.580+0.111i -0.445 0.124 0.003

    T 1.000 0.503 0.000 -0.299-0.001i -0.299+0.001i 0.849 -0.455 -0.020

    O 1.000 0.304 0.000 -0.749-0.092i -0.749+0.092i -0.142 0.771 0.080R 1.000 0.149 0.000 -0.461-0.041i -0.461+0.041i -0.531 -0.309 -0.169

    S 1.000 0.040 0.000 -0.150-0.016i -0.150+0.016i -0.229 -0.226 0.784

    1.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

    Note:

    is imaginary sign.

    Since the expected transition matrix has mainly nonzero elements on the three main diagonals

    and elements close to one on the main diagonal, it is rather close to an identity matrix, which

    explains why the different eigenvalues have a large modulus , close to one.

    Finally the migration risk created by the assumption of stochastic transition matrix can be

    measured by means of covariances between the transition probabilities cov

    . There is

    a large number of such covariances, that is

    . We provide in Table 8, the estimated standard

    errors:

    var

    , which correspond to migration of the same type for two

    firms and can be directly compared to the expectations given in Table 6.

    4.5 Factor models

    Let us now consider the possibility of introducing serially dependent stochastic transition matrices,

    by means of latent factors which determine the latent means.

    Recall that the eigenvalues of any transition matrix have a modulus smaller or equal to .

    22

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    26/56

    Table 8: Standard error of stochastic transition probabilities

    1 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

    2 0.000 0.116 0.047 0.016 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

    3 0.000 0.000 0.050 0.050 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

    4 0.000 0.000 0.014 0.033 0.068 0.000 0.000 0.000

    5 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.069 0.067 0.253 0.000 0.000

    6 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.005 0.057 0.033 0.023 0.084

    7 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.517 0.246 1.179

    4.5.1 Static factor analysis

    In the first step, we perform a static factor analysis based on the latent means estimated per year.

    For this purpose, we consider the series of estimated means in Table 20 [in the appendix], where

    column number

    , or AAA, corresponds to the identifying constraints. Each column represents

    a time series of latent means. We provide in Table 21[in the appendix] the historical variance-

    covariance matrix of these time series, and perform its spectral decomposition [see Table 22 in

    the appendix]. It is observed that the largest eigenvalue is significantly larger than the other ones,

    which indicates a one factor model.

    4.5.2 Approximate linear analysis of the factor model

    Let us now consider the one factor model:

    (18)

    where

    ,

    are independent standard Gaussian variables, and

    are de-

    terministic coefficients. The

    parameter provides a measure of the expected risk averaged on

    time, whereas the time effect is captured by the sensitivity coefficient

    with respect to the factor

    . When the factor increases with aggregate risk, the larger

    , the larger is the sensitivity with

    respect to the aggregate risk.

    23

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    27/56

    Since the latent means can be well approximated by the cross- sectional estimates

    , we first

    consider the approximate model:

    where

    are , and the measurement errors are approximately

    Gaussian. Note that a factor is defined up to a multiplicative factor and that the variance of the

    innovation

    can been fixed to one for identification . The advantage of this specification is that

    it is a special case of linear factor models, for which standard softwares are available .

    Table 9 displays the first and second order autocorrelations of the estimated latent means for

    each rating class. Indeed, before applying the usual Kalman filter methodology, it is important to

    test for stationarity; we observe immediately that there is no unit root in the dynamics of the latent

    means, and then in the factor dynamics.

    Table 9: First and second order correlation of means estimates

    First 0.265 0.498 0.286 0.507 0.590 0.416

    Second 0.270 0.186 0.084 0.155 0.156 -0.064

    The M.L. estimation of the approximated latent one-factor model is reported in Table 10,where

    the error terms

    have been assumed uncorrelated, with different variances

    .

    In a one factor model the factor is identified up to a scale effect. In the present estimation

    the identification restriction provides a factor which is in a positive relationship with default risk.

    Larger the factor value, larger the expected score, that is the expected probability of default. As

    expected the sensitivity coefficients have all the same sign and tend to be much larger for the risky

    The last identification restriction consists in choosing a factor which increases with aggregate risk, that is fixing

    the sign in order to get positive sensitivity coefficients. As already mentioned, the error terms

    are due to the estimation error. They are approximately Gaussian by

    Central Limit Theorem. They are also conditionally heteroscedastic. The heteroscedasticity is not completely taken

    into account in this first step, providing inefficient, but consistent estimators.

    24

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    28/56

    Table 10: Estimation result of the approximate model

    5.657 6.524 7.012 7.929 10.700 12.818

    (0.082) (0.005) (0.041) (0.053) (0.384) (0.085)

    0.003 0.019 0.03 0.231 0.049 5.829

    (2.0e-4) (2.11e-3) (2.29e-3) (1.62e-2) (3.72e-3) 0.121

    1.5e-3 0.028 0.029 0.151 0.039 0.361

    (4.3e-9) (1.2e-4) (6.0e-4) (0.021) (1.8-4) (0.013)

    0.02

    (0.011)

    Note: The standard errors are in parentheses.

    class (remind that

    for the AAA).

    Of course, the analysis of heterogeneity is more difficult, since we have to distinguish between

    the whole heterogeneity and the residual one. More precisely the quantitative score is given by:

    Therefore its variance is equal to:

    var

    var

    It involves two components corresponding to the factor effect and the innovation, respectively.

    The ordering of whole heterogeneity discussed in Section 4.3 is expected on the sum of the compo-

    nents, but a large value of the variance of the score can be obtained in different ways: for instance,

    for bad risk CCC, the effect of the factor ( ) is very large, with a residual variance of

    . Conversely for high rating AAA, there is by convention no factor effect (

    ), and a

    rather large residual variance

    .

    The filtered factor values are given in Table 11 and reported in Figure 4. The evolution of

    the factor is similar to the evolution of the total default rate as reported for instance in Brady,

    Bos(2002), Chart 5, or Exhibit 4 in Hamilton, Cantor and Ou (2002).

    25

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    29/56

    Table 11: filtered latent variable

    0.967 0.653 -0.602 -1.192 -0.625 -0.730 -1.607

    -0.852 -0.03 0.493 0.774 1.095 1.607

    In fact the factor is essentially capturing the parallel evolution of downgrade probabilities, as

    seen in Figure 5,

    It is natural to compare this factor to some indicator of growth or business cycle. As noted in

    Bangia et alii (2002), such a comparison is not easy to perform since the (U.S.) economy is mainly

    in expansion during the period. More precisely the months of recession are from the third of 1981

    to the fourth of 1982, the third of 1990 to the first of 1991, and the whole year of 2001 from the

    NBER report [at NBER website]. Moreover the evolution is not in the same direction, which may

    be due to either a lag, or an advance of the credit cycle with respect to the general cycle. We also

    observe that the underlying factors do not feature jumps, but has some smoother variation. This

    observed feature means that a dynamic of the factor by means of a three state Markov chain, to

    distinguish cycle through, cycle normal, cycle peak [as in Nickell et alii (2000), Bangia et

    alii (2002)] is likely misspecified.

    4.5.3 The number of factors

    Before implementing a more complicated estimation method, we have to check if it would be

    necessary to introduce more factors. Different diagnostic tools are considered below.

    First, the estimated means and their predictions deduced from the approximated latent factor

    models are displayed in Figure 6, for different rating categories. The goodness of fit is rather good

    for such a single factor model and the limited number of available temporal observations. The

    factor model tends to smooth the time series of means and lacks the small risk observed in 1993, for

    26

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    30/56

    the bad rating categories (BB,B,CC) or the high risk observed in 2003 for the high rating categories.

    Clearly the introduction of a two-factor model will provide a first factor measuring the global risk

    and a second factor to opposite the investment grades (AA,A,BBB) from the speculative categories

    (BB,B,CCC). Second, we have computed the difference between the average square estimates

    (

    and the estimated (diagonal) variance-covariance matrix and computed the

    spectral decomposition of the difference (see Table 24 in the appendix). Even if the first eigenvalue

    is significantly larger than one, its value is rather small.

    4.5.4 Simulated maximum likelihood of the factor probit model

    Finally the one-factor probit model has been estimated by a simulated maximum likelihood ap-

    proach, which is (asymptotically) more efficient from a theoretical point of view than the approxi-

    mated ML approach, essentially for the sensitivity (micro) parameters. The estimation results are

    given in Table 12, where the number of replications has been fixed to 2000. Whereas the estimated

    and

    coefficients are rather similar to those obtained with the approximated Kalman filter, the

    estimation of

    and the cutting points can be different, which reveal the lack of robustness for

    heterogeneity estimation:

    Table 12: SML estimation result of one factor model

    5.661 6.776 7.326 8.2540 10.950 12.71

    0.003 0.437 0.017 0.2467 0.057 0.823

    0.431 0.022 0.280 0.242 1.257 1.229

    0.01

    To facilitate the interpretation of heterogeneity in terms of the rating category, the total latent

    variance of the quantitative score is given in Table 13, with the proportion of the variance explained

    by the factor.

    The total variances per grade are ranked approximately with the same order than the historical

    27

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    31/56

    Table 13: Heterogeneity

    Rating AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC

    Total variance 1.00 0.19 0.19 0.08 0.18 1.58 23.32

    Part of explained variance(in %) 0.00 .01 99.19 0.35 55.26 0.20 30.98

    variance of the probabilities to stay in the same category. Some improved smoothing latent factor

    values can be derived by using the large cross-sectional dimension, which allows to avoid the

    complicated nonlinear filtering. If

    denote the coefficient estimates of Table 12, we have

    approximately:

    Then a smoothed value of

    taking into account the improved estimates will be the OLS esti-

    mator in the regression above:

    (19)

    These values have to be demeaned and standardized to satisfy the identification restriction. The

    standardization is performed by dividing these factor values by the standard deviation of

    E

    E

    . The improved smoothed values are given in Table 14.

    Table 14: Smoothed factor values

    0.775 0.715 -0.431 -1.879 -0.440 -0.151 -1.331

    -1.052 -0.101 0.829 0.619 1.262 1.185

    and reported in Figure 7 in the Appendix.

    28

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    32/56

    5 Prediction of future ratings

    An advantage of the unobservable factor ordered probit model is to be convenient for prediction

    purpose, and to allow for an analysis of migration correlation. Let us first recall the prediction

    formulas and apply them on the S&P data set.

    5.1 Prediction for a given firm

    Let us first consider a given firm. If the future values of the factor

    were known,

    the transition at horizon

    would be:

    and the distribution of its rating at date when its rating at date is would correspond

    to the

    row of the matrix

    .

    When the future factor values are not observed, the matrix above becomes stochastic, and has

    to be integrated with respect to

    conditional on

    . The integrated matrix is:

    E

    This matrix has no explicit expression, but the prediction of the rating at

    can be per-

    formed by simulation along the following steps:

    Step 1: Simulate a future path of the noise

    , and deduce the associated future

    factor values

    by applying the autoregressive formula;

    Step 2: Compute the matrix

    and its row number

    :

    ,

    say.

    Step 3: Replicate the simulation

    times and compute

    , which is

    an approximation of the row of the matrix

    .

    29

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    33/56

    5.2 Prediction for two given firms

    Let us now consider two firms and , say, where ratings are known at date . Their joint transition

    are summarized by a matrix , which gives the probability that firms and currently in

    grate

    and

    , respectively, are in grade

    and

    at , say. If the future value of the factor is

    known, this joint transition matrix is:

    where

    denotes the tensor product, which associates with the matrices

    , the matrix

    with block decomposition

    . If the sequence of future values is known, the joint migration

    matrix at horizon becomes:

    When only the current factor value is known, this matrix has to be integrated to get:

    E

    E

    This matrix can not be written in general as a tensor product, which means that migration

    correlations have been created by the common effect of the unobservable factor. As above this

    matrix has no explicit expression, but can be well approximated by simulation.

    5.3 Prediction of future ratings

    Let us now consider the prediction of future ratings for the S&P data base. For this purpose the

    factor value will be fixed to its filtered value computed for 2002, that is

    , and the

    parameters to their estimates given in Table 12.

    We perform replications of a simulated factor path to get the matrices

    ,

    at horizon 1 year, 2 year, 5 year and 10 year. The matrices for are given in Table

    30

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    34/56

    25 in the appendix. We also compute the difference

    for

    the following joint migrations corresponding to joint up grades , to joint

    stability and to joint downgrades . (see Table 15, Table

    26, Table 27 and Table 28 in the appendix) to get more information about the term structure of the

    migration correlations.

    Table 15: The key cells in

    for 1 year horizon

    co-movement AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC

    AAA

    AA 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    up A 0.0000 0.0298 0.0010 0.0231 0.0002 0.0274

    1 BBB 0.0000 0.0010 0.0002 -0.0003 0.0000 0.0034

    bucket BB 0.0000 0.0237 0.0012 0.0234 1e-04 0.0367

    B 0.0000 0.0002 0.0000 -0.0004 0.0000 0.0006

    CCC 0.0000 0.0274 0.0034 0.0307 0.0006 0.1184

    AAA -0.0001 -0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0705 0.0000 0.0000

    AA -0.0001 0.0000 0.0001 0.0000 0.0608 0.0000 0.0000

    unchanged A 0.0000 0.0001 0.1300 -0.0008 0.1627 0.0016 0.0733

    BBB 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0008 0.0001 -0.0616 0.0001 -0.0005BB 0.0705 0.0680 0.1627 0.0616 0.2037 0.0599 0.1244

    B -1e-04 -1e-04 0.0017 0.0000 0.0020 0.0000 0.0011

    CCC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0733 -0.0005 0.1244 0.0011 0.1407

    AAA 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    AA 0.0000 0.0000 0.0002 0.0000 0.0003 0.0000 0.0004

    down A 0.0000 0.0003 0.1099 0.0011 0.0868 0.0018 0.0886

    1 BBB 0.0000 0.0000 0.0011 0.0000 -0.0001 0.0000 0.0018

    bucket BB -0.0019 -0.003 0.0868 -0.0001 0.0823 -0.0034 0.1085

    B 0.0000 0.0000 0.0018 0.0000 -0.0034 0.0001 0.0029

    CCC 0.0000 4e-04 0.0886 0.0018 0.1085 0.0029 0.1789

    Rather large values can be observed even for rather high rating sector A, but these values tend

    to diminish when the horizon increases. This result is not surprising since the current rating is less

    informative when the horizon increases.

    31

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    35/56

    6 Concluding remarks

    The aim of this paper was to implement a factor probit model for rating transitions as suggested

    in the theoretical and applied literature, to see if such a specification is suitable for regular compu-

    tation of CreditVaR. The message is fourfold: i) a one-factor model seems to produce reasonable

    prediction of the expected risk per rating category,

    ii) but the estimated heterogeneity is not robust, which can have severe consequences for the

    reliability of CreditVaR computed from these estimations. This is partly a consequence of the data

    bases, which are currently available and do not include a large number of years, with data of good

    quality. But this is also a consequence of the transitions themselves, and of the few number of

    down- or up-grades of more of one bucket in a given year.

    (iii) It seems preferable to introduce an unobservable factor instead of assuming it related to

    some macromeasure of the business cycle. In some sense the available data set on credit migration

    is sufficiently rich at the aggregate level to reveal the credit cycles.

    iv) Finally the estimation of such a nonlinear dynamic model involves rather sophisticated

    estimation techniques such as simulated based estimation methods or nonlinear filtering, which

    are not commonly used by the research-development groups of the banks and not available in

    standard software.

    32

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    36/56

    REFERENCES

    Albanese, C., Campolieti, G., Chen, O., and A., Zavidonov (2003)a: Credit Barrier Models,

    forthcoming in Risk, 16.

    Albanese, C., and O., Chen (2003)b: Implied Migration Rates from Credit Barrier Models,

    Working paper.

    Avellaneda, M., and J., Zhu (2001): Distance to Default, Risk, 14, 125-129.

    Bangia,A., Diebold, F., Kronimus, A., Schlagen, C., and T., Schuermann (2002): Ratings

    Migration and Business Cycle, with Application to Credit Portfolio Stress Testing, Journal of

    Banking and Finance, 26,445-474.

    Basle Committee on Banking Supervision (2002): Quantitative Impact Study 3, Technical

    Guidance, Bank of International Settlement, Basle.

    Brady, B., and R., Bos (2002): Record Default in 2001. The Result of Poor Credit Quality

    and a Weak Economy, Standard & Poors, February.

    Brady, B., Vazza, D., and R. J. Bos (2003), Ratings Performance 2002: Default, Transition,

    Recovery, and Spreads . down-loadable on the website of Standard & Poors.

    Carty, L. (1997): Moodys Rating Migration and Credit Quality Correlation, 1920-1996,

    Moodys Investor Service, July.

    Cheung, S., (1996): Provincial Credit Ratings in Canada: An Ordered Probit Analysis.

    Working paper 96-6, Bank of Canada, Ottawa.

    Das, S., and G., Geng (2002): Modeling the Processes of Correlated Default, Working paper,

    Santa-Clara University.

    De Servigny, A., and O., Renault (2002): Default Correlation: Empirical Evidence, Standard

    & Poors, September.

    Duffie, D., and K., Singleton (1999): Modeling the Term Structure of Defaultable Bonds,

    Review of Financial Studies, 12, 687-720.

    Erturk, E. (2000): Default Correlation Among Investment Grade Borrowers,, Journal of

    33

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    37/56

    Fixed Income, 9,55-60.

    Foulcher, S., Gourieroux, C., and A., Tiomo (2003): Term Structure of Defaults and Ratings,

    forthcoming Assurance et Gestion du Risque.

    Frey, R., and A., McNeil (2001): Modeling Dependent Defaults, Working paper, Zurich.

    Gagliardini, P., and C., Gourieroux (2003) a: Stochastic Migration Models, CREST DP .

    Gagliardini, P., and C., Gourieroux (2003) b: Migration Correlation: Definition and Consis-

    tent Estimation, forthcoming Journal of Banking and Finance.

    Gollinger, T., and J., Morgan (1993): Calculation of an Efficient Frontier for a Commercial

    Loan Portfolio, Journal of Portfolio Management, 39-46.

    Gourieroux, C., and A., Monfort (1995): Simulated Based Estimation Methods, Oxford

    University Press.

    Gourieroux, C., and A., Monfort (2003): Equidependence In Qualitative and Duration Models

    with Application to Credit Risk, CREST DP.

    Gouriroux, C., and A., Monfort (2004): Error-in-Factor Model, CREST DP.

    Gupton, G., Finger,C., and M., Bhatia (1997): Creditmetrics: Technical Document, Techni-

    cal Report,

    Hamilton, D., Cantor, R., and S., Ou (2002): Default & Recovery Rates of Corporate Bond

    Issuers:A Statistical Review of Moodys Ratings Performance 1970-2001. Working paper, down-

    loadable at Moodys website.

    Jarrow, R., Lando, D., and S., Turnbull (1997): A Markov Model for the Term Structure of

    Credit Risk Spreads, Review of Financial Studies, 10(2), 481-523.

    Kijima, M., and K., Komoribayashi (1998): A Markov Chain Model for Valuing Credit Risk

    Derivatives, Journal of Derivatives 6(1), 97-108.

    Kijima, M., and E., Suzuki (2002): A Multivariate Markov Model for Simulating Correlated

    Defaults, Journal of Risk.

    Klaassen, L., and A., Lucas (2002): Dynamic Credit Risk Modeling.D.P.

    34

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    38/56

    Lando, D. (1998): On Cox Processes and Credit Risky Securities, Review of Derivatives

    Research, 2, 99-120.

    Li, D. (2000): On Default Correlation: A Copula Function Approach, The Journal of Fixed

    Income; 9,4; 43-54.

    Lucas, D. (1995): Default Correlation and Credit Analysis, The Journal of Fixed Income;

    76-87.

    Merton, R. (1974): On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: the Risk Structure of Interest Rates,

    Journal of Finance, 19(2), 449-470.

    Nagpal,K., and R., Bahar (1999): An Analytical Approach For Credit Risk Analysis Under

    Correlated Default, Credit metrics monitor, 51-79, April.

    Nagpal,K., and R., Bahar (2001)a: Credit Risk In Presence of Correlations, Part 1: Historical

    Data For US Corporate, Risk.

    Nagpal,K., and R., Bahar (2001)b: Measuring Default Correlation, Risk, 14,129-132.

    Nickell P., Perraudin, W., and S., Varotto (2000): Stability of Rating Transitions, Journal of

    Banking & Finance, 24, 203-227.

    Stevenson, B., and M., Fadil (1995): Modern Portfolio Theory: Can It Work for Commercial

    Loan ?, Commercial Lending Review, 10, 9-12.

    Yu, F. (2002): Correlated Defaults In Reduced Form Models, Working paper, University of

    California, Irvine.

    35

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    39/56

    Table 16: Estimates of cutting points by ML

    Year

    1981 1.3661 4.0453 6.7862 7.9719 11.1906 14.4934 21.7740

    1982 1.2328 5.4060 5.7112 6.3915 7.4043 12.5313 13.1165

    1983 0.8836 4.9459 5.3035 6.3230 7.3473 14.3599 14.5940

    1984 0.4762 4.5752 5.0654 6.0260 7.0337 13.5765 13.8405

    1985 1.4730 5.6924 5.9981 6.6785 7.6913 12.8185 13.4035

    1986 1.3981 6.1111 6.8695 8.2936 9.3165 15.6508 16.2461

    1987 1.6781 3.0130 3.4471 4.9318 5.3918 10.2598 10.6971

    1988 1.7516 6.3559 6.5843 7.4906 8.5181 12.4404 12.8253

    1989 1.6096 6.2486 6.4738 7.3797 8.4072 12.3099 12.6922

    1990 1.7523 6.3558 6.5841 7.4904 8.5179 12.4398 12.82471991 1.7528 6.3558 6.5841 7.4904 8.5178 12.4403 12.8253

    1992 1.3120 6.3407 6.8013 7.4614 8.4754 12.4825 13.0590

    1993 1.7714 6.4200 6.6501 7.5566 8.5842 12.5176 12.8985

    1994 1.3740 5.6667 6.1096 6.8535 7.8650 12.6246 13.1608

    1995 1.7346 6.4124 6.7819 7.6652 8.7394 12.6521 12.9990

    1996 1.4842 5.9733 6.3003 7.0845 8.0982 12.3535 12.9919

    1997 1.7430 6.3529 6.5814 7.4876 8.5151 12.4344 12.8191

    1998 1.7367 6.3444 6.5732 7.4797 8.5071 12.4302 12.8151

    2000 1.7455 6.2718 6.4996 7.4063 8.4337 12.3694 12.7540

    2001 1.7523 6.3540 6.5822 7.4885 8.5160 12.4418 12.82682002 1.7521 6.3554 6.5837 7.4900 8.5175 12.4392 12.8243

    36

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    40/56

    Table 17: Estimates of latent means by ML

    Year

    1981 2.9240 5.5025 7.3725 10.4454 11.2920 14.5371

    1982 4.8464 5.6891 6.1221 6.9520 10.2301 12.93371983 4.3121 5.2506 5.8132 6.8925 11.0118 14.4256

    1984 3.9321 4.9777 5.5373 6.4559 10.1781 13.8242

    1985 5.2212 5.7261 6.4060 7.2337 10.5059 12.9768

    1986 4.2245 6.1843 7.6656 8.7729 13.5479 16.1361

    1987 2.4434 3.3273 4.2742 5.1666 7.8905 10.4983

    1988 5.8423 6.5490 7.0491 8.0426 10.5814 12.6925

    1989 5.5406 6.4430 6.9350 7.7662 10.3837 12.6760

    1990 5.7538 6.5526 7.0769 8.0415 10.9218 12.7546

    1991 5.6897 6.5506 7.0729 8.0420 11.0193 12.7536

    1992 5.7174 6.5560 7.1403 7.8629 10.5612 12.85171993 5.6975 6.6095 7.1416 8.0309 10.0311 12.6133

    1994 5.0663 5.8367 6.4616 7.3098 10.2538 12.9480

    1995 5.7881 6.7248 7.1926 8.1587 10.6233 12.8957

    1996 5.6740 6.2695 6.6451 7.5289 10.0106 12.6047

    1997 5.6163 6.5420 7.0434 7.9396 10.3595 12.6089

    1998 5.6073 6.5370 7.0784 8.0356 10.5839 12.6892

    1999 5.6149 6.4652 6.9496 7.9675 10.8201 12.6900

    2000 5.7456 6.5506 7.0677 8.0415 10.8981 12.7421

    2001 5.6990 6.5483 7.0740 8.0409 11.2624 12.7868

    2002 5.9045 6.5550 7.1595 8.0407 11.0484 12.7882

    37

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    41/56

    Table 18: Estimates of latent standard deviations by ML

    Year

    1981 0.7560 0.8638 0.3619 1.5557 0.0624 0.0341

    1982 0.4357 0.0172 0.2267 0.3773 1.6596 0.28891983 0.4133 0.0318 0.3698 0.4718 2.1354 0.0598

    1984 0.4167 0.0483 0.4454 0.3881 1.9095 0.0169

    1985 0.4360 0.0172 0.2272 0.3774 1.6596 0.2888

    1986 1.4233 0.0468 0.5999 0.3542 2.2799 0.1247

    1987 0.3647 0.0017 0.5493 0.1703 1.5875 0.1695

    1988 0.4667 0.0224 0.2960 0.3593 1.3576 0.2073

    1989 0.4655 0.0204 0.2957 0.3701 1.3576 0.2132

    1990 0.4668 0.0224 0.2960 0.3593 1.3577 0.2072

    1991 0.4668 0.0224 0.2960 0.3593 1.3577 0.2072

    1992 0.4551 0.0178 0.2457 0.3470 1.6591 0.29051993 0.4650 0.0225 0.2887 0.3657 1.3589 0.2068

    1994 0.4259 0.0205 0.2093 0.3103 1.5746 0.2509

    1995 0.4298 0.0313 0.2647 0.3636 1.3586 0.1959

    1996 0.1866 0.0148 0.2276 0.3624 1.4301 0.2482

    1997 0.4670 0.0224 0.2963 0.3593 1.3582 0.2071

    1998 0.4665 0.0225 0.2963 0.3591 1.3585 0.2075

    1999 0.4665 0.0218 0.2974 0.3596 1.3607 0.2046

    2000 0.4668 0.0224 0.2960 0.3593 1.3576 0.2072

    2001 0.4669 0.0224 0.2955 0.3595 1.3576 0.2074

    2002 0.4668 0.0224 0.2960 0.3594 1.3577 0.2073

    38

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    42/56

    Table 19:

    -goodness of fit by ML under three constraintsYear Case 1 Case 2 Case 3

    1990 0.030 0.032 0.028

    1991 0.027 0.031 0.023

    1992 0.046 0.037 0.154

    1993 0.067 0.067 0.117

    1994 0.013 0.014 0.033

    1995 0.011 0.006 0.012

    1996 0.052 0.034 0.121

    1997 0.004 0.005 0.087

    1998 0.113 0.122 0.0121999 0.013 0.009 0.012

    2000 0.014 0.012 0.011

    2001 0.032 0.030 0.034

    2002 0.031 0.030 0.050

    Note: Case1: Only cutting points are unchanged; Case 2: Cutting points and variances are unchanged, Case 3: Cutting

    points and means are unchanged.

    Table 20: Estimated latent means when cutting points and variances are constant

    Year 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

    c.p. 1.6497 6.2765 6.5597 7.4233 8.4603 12.5324 12.9579

    1.000 0.433 0.022 0.28 0.343 1.410 0.218

    m 1990 0.000 5.7248 6.5291 7.0309 7.9798 10.9591 12.8786

    e 1991 0.000 5.6636 6.5271 7.0242 7.9362 11.0634 12.8781

    a 1992 0.000 5.6705 6.5206 7.0042 7.8307 10.5696 12.8042

    n 1993 0.000 5.6101 6.5203 7.0259 7.9093 9.9879 12.6414

    s 1994 0.000 5.6519 6.5215 6.9756 7.8951 10.4830 12.7901

    1995 0.000 5.6429 6.5202 6.9593 7.8950 10.4332 12.8302

    1996 0.000 5.5652 6.5144 6.9489 7.8718 10.2800 12.7038m 1997 0.000 5.5719 6.5215 7.0002 7.8775 10.3869 12.7262

    e 1998 0.000 5.5827 6.5245 7.0415 7.9467 10.6204 12.8053

    a 1999 0.000 5.5991 6.5254 6.9858 7.9901 10.9386 12.8863

    n 2000 0.000 5.7165 6.5275 7.0214 7.9708 10.9364 12.8643

    s 2001 0.000 5.6751 6.5266 7.0283 7.9909 11.3175 12.9118

    2002 0.000 5.8703 6.5315 7.1108 7.9834 11.0926 12.9162

    Note: c.p. stands for cutting point.

    39

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    43/56

    Table 21: Variance and covariance matrix of mean estimates

    0.00676 2.826e-04 0.00247 0.00198 0.01856 0.00444

    0.00028 2.143e-05 0.00015 0.00020 0.00146 0.00031

    0.00246 1.525e-04 0.00172 0.00121 0.00792 0.00147

    0.00198 1.992e-04 0.00121 0.00279 0.01515 0.00310

    0.01856 1.464e-03 0.00792 0.01515 0.14754 0.03078

    0.00444 3.147e-04 0.00147 0.00310 0.03078 0.00720

    Table 22: Eigenvalues and eigenvectors of variance and covariance matrix

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7

    Values 1.584e-01 4.942e-03 1.487e-03 8.490e-04 3.082e-04 1.541e-06

    V 0.126 0.917 -0.191 -0.063 -0.321 0.002

    E 0.009 0.023 0.035 -0.009 0.043 -0.998

    C 0.053 0.358 0.478 0.427 0.675 0.051

    T 0.100 0.033 0.782 -0.574 -0.218 0.024O 0.964 -0.158 -0.009 0.185 -0.103 -0.001

    R 0.203 0.070 -0.350 -0.671 0.617 0.024

    Table 23: Variance matrix of prediction errors

    1 2 3 4 5 6 71 0.004 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.004 0.001

    2 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.000

    3 0.001 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.000

    4 0.001 0.000 0.001 0.002 0.009 0.002

    5 0.004 0.001 0.002 0.009 0.073 0.016

    6 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.002 0.016 0.004

    40

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    44/56

    Table 24: Eigenvalues and eigenvectors of the difference of matrices

    1 2 3 4 5 6

    Values 0.074 0.004 0.000 -0.001 -0.021 -0.127

    V 0.057 0.950 0.307 0.005 -0.010 -0.008

    E 0.010 0.022 -0.053 -0.998 -0.003 -0.001

    C 0.029 0.304 -0.950 0.058 -0.023 -0.001

    T 0.093 0.011 -0.018 -0.001 0.995 -0.010

    O 0.990 -0.065 0.012 0.008 -0.092 -0.077

    R 0.078 0.003 0.003 0.000 0.003 0.997

    41

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    45/56

    Table 25: The prediction of transition matrix,

    Horizon AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC D

    AAA 0.9505 0.0495 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    AA 0.0000 0.9141 0.0847 0.0012 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    1 A 0.0000 0.0334 0.8192 0.1472 0.0002 0.0000 0 .0000 0.0000

    year BBB 0.0000 0.0001 0.1191 0.8432 0.0375 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    BB 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0487 0.7141 0.2372 0.0000 0.0000

    B 0.0000 0.0001 0.0007 0.0053 0.0177 0.7803 0.1441 0.0519CCC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.2014 0.4125 0.3860

    AAA 0.9034 0.0923 0.0042 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    AA 0.0000 0.8381 0.1477 0.0141 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    2 A 0.0000 0.0550 0.7060 0.2336 0.0054 0.0000 0 .0000 0.0000

    year BBB 0.0000 0.0038 0.1993 0.7295 0.0585 0.0088 0.0000 0.0000

    BB 0.0000 0.0000 0.0060 0.0753 0.5281 0.3463 0.0326 0.0117

    B 0.0000 0.0002 0.0017 0.0096 0.0268 0.6419 0.1719 0.1479

    CCC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0011 0.0036 0.2418 0.2057 0.5476

    AAA 0.7758 0.1884 0.0307 0.0050 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    AA 0.0000 0.6598 0.2563 0.0802 0.0033 0.0005 0.0000 0.0000

    5 A 0.0000 0.1037 0.4968 0.3627 0.0278 0.0080 0 .0007 0.0004

    year BBB 0.0000 0.0283 0.3069 0.5355 0.0764 0.0422 0.0059 0.0048

    BB 0.0000 0.0015 0.0319 0.1085 0.2205 0.4029 0.0936 0.1411

    B 0.0000 0.0006 0.0060 0.0185 0.0325 0.4040 0.1279 0.4105

    CCC 0.0000 0.0001 0.0012 0.0048 0.0105 0.1805 0.0634 0.7395

    AAA 0.6019 0.2736 0.0886 0.0332 0.0019 0.0006 0.0001 0.0001

    AA 0.0000 0.4636 0.3207 0.1906 0.0159 0.0071 0.0010 0.001110 A 0.0000 0.1298 0.3861 0.3885 0.0475 0.0330 0.0059 0.0093

    year BBB 0.0000 0.0652 0.3266 0.4114 0.0673 0.0741 0.0162 0.0393

    BB 0.0000 0.0082 0.0589 0.1040 0.0721 0.2760 0.0789 0.4018

    B 0.0000 0.0019 0.0124 0.0241 0.0232 0.2023 0.0629 0.6732

    CCC 0.0000 0.0005 0.0036 0.0080 0.0093 0.0906 0.0285 0.8596

    42

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    46/56

    Table 26: The key cells in

    for 2-year horizon

    co-movement AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC

    AAA AA 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    up A 0.0000 0.0445 -0.0009 0.0292 0.0001 0.0260

    1 BBB 0.0000 -0.0009 0.0023 -0.0099 0.0005 0.0037

    bucket BB 0.0000 0.0292 -0.0099 0.0187 -0.0011 0.0230

    B 0.0000 0.0001 0.0005 -0.0011 0.0001 0.0009

    CCC 0.0000 0.0260 0.0037 0.0230 0.0009 0.1008

    AAA 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0012 0.0930 -0.0006 0.0001

    AA 0.0000 0.0001 -0.0014 -0.0013 0.0856 -0.0003 -0.0003

    A 0.0000 -0.0014 0.1678 -0.0129 0.1915 0.0006 0.0513

    unchanged BBB -0.0012 -0.0013 -0.0129 -0.0002 0.0655 -0.0020 -0.0039

    BB 0.0930 0.0856 0.1915 0.0655 0.2104 0.0678 0.0861

    B -0.0006 -0.0003 0.0006 -0.0020 0.0678 0.0018 -0.0021

    CCC 0.0001 -0.0003 0.0513 -0.0039 0.0861 -0.0021 0.0672

    AAA 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 -0.0037 0.0000 -0.0001

    AA 0.0000 0.0009 -0.0070 0.0007 -0.0107 0.0008 -0.0024

    down A 0.0000 -0.0070 0.1425 -0.0005 0.0907 -0.0053 0.0821

    1 BBB 0.0003 0.0007 -0.0005 0.0004 -0.0021 0.0009 0.0017

    bucket BB -0.0037 -0.0107 0.0907 -0.0021 0.0672 -0.0131 0.0817

    B 0.0000 0.0008 -0.0053 0.0009 -0.0131 0.0028 -0.0050

    CCC -0.0001 -0.0024 0.0821 0.0017 0.0817 -0.0050 0.1685

    43

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    47/56

    Table 27: The key cells in

    for 5-year horizon

    co-movement AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC

    AAA AA 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    up A 0.0000 0.0643 -0.0080 0.0287 0.0002 0.0174

    1 BBB 0.0000 -0.0080 0.0191 -0.0172 0.0034 0.0030

    bucket BB 0.0000 0.0287 -0.0172 0.0124 -0.0006 0.0124

    B 0.0000 0.0002 0.0034 -0.0006 0.0005 0.0018

    CCC 0.0000 0.0174 0.0030 0.0124 0.0018 0.0454

    AAA 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0045 0.0623 -0.0011 0.0000

    AA 0.0000 0.0036 -0.0070 -0.0045 0.0508 0.0013 -0.0002

    A 0.0000 -0.0070 0.1413 -0.0385 0.1110 0.0015 0.0113

    unchanged BBB -0.0045 -0.0045 -0.0385 0.0094 0.0249 -0.0052 -0.0035

    BB 0.0623 0.0508 0.1110 0.0249 0.0813 0.0363 0.0177

    B -0.0011 0.0013 0.0015 -0.0052 0.0363 0.0065 0.0006

    CCC 0.0000 -0.0002 0.0113 -0.0035 0.0177 0.0006 0.0079

    AAA 0.0000 -0.0002 -0.0004 0.0021 0.0005 -0.0002 -0.0001

    AA -0.0002 0.0113 -0.0258 0.0053 -0.0090 0.0033 -0.0039

    down A -0.0004 -0.0258 0.1216 -0.0007 0.0531 -0.0087 0.0385

    1 BBB 0.0021 0.0053 -0.0007 0.0024 0.0023 0.0028 0.0076

    bucket BB 0.0005 -0.0090 0.0531 0.0023 0.0404 -0.0062 0.0360

    B -0.0002 0.0033 -0.0087 0.0028 -0.0062 0.0046 -0.0048

    CCC -0.0001 -0.0039 0.0385 0.0076 0.0360 -0.0048 0.0893

    44

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    48/56

    Table 28: The key cells in

    for 10-year horizon

    co-movement AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC

    AAA AA 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

    up A 0.0000 0.0531 -0.0097 0.0145 0.0007 0.0070

    1 BBB 0.0000 -0.0097 0.0354 -0.0166 0.0041 0.0002

    bucket BB 0.0000 0.0145 -0.0166 0.0072 0.0000 0.0052

    B 0.0000 0.0007 0.0041 0.0000 0.0005 0.0009

    CCC 0.0000 0.0070 0.0002 0.0052 0.0009 0.0122

    AAA 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0007 -0.0055 0.0175 0.0005 0.0000

    AAA 0.0000 0.0125 -0.0100 -0.0083 0.0123 0.0030 0.0000

    AA -0.0007 -0.0100 0.0763 -0.0422 0.0293 0.0013 0.0020

    A -0.0055 -0.0083 -0.0422 0.0232 0.0033 -0.0030 -0.0014

    unchanged BBB 0.0175 0.0123 0.0293 0.0033 0.0114 0.0076 0.0024

    BB 0.0005 0.0030 0.0013 -0.0030 0.0076 0.0047 0.0006

    B 0.0000 0.0000 0.0020 -0.0014 0.0024 0.0006 0.0017

    CCC 0.0004 -0.0013 -0.0025 0.0036 0.0086 -0.0001 -0.0002

    AA -0.0013 0.0308 -0.0351 0.0083 0.0068 0.0026 -0.0018

    down A -0.0025 -0.0351 0.0677 0.0021 0.0220 -0.0039 0.0056

    1 BBB 0.0036 0.0083 0.0021 0.0026 0.0051 0.0016 0.0119

    bucket BB 0.0086 0.0068 0.0220 0.0051 0.0260 0.0011 0.0289

    B -0.0001 0.0026 -0.0039 0.0016 0.0011 0.0014 -0.0017

    CCC -0.0002 -0.0018 0.0056 0.0119 0.0289 -0.0017 0.0282

    45

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    49/56

    Figure 1a Estimates of the mean

    m1

    85 90 95 00

    3

    4

    5

    6

    m2

    85 90 95 00

    4

    5

    6

    m3

    85 90 95 00

    5

    6

    7

    m4

    85 90 95 00

    5

    6

    7

    8

    9

    10

    m5

    85 90 95 00

    8

    9

    10

    11

    12

    13

    m6

    85 90 95 00

    11

    12

    13

    14

    15

    16

    46

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    50/56

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    51/56

    Figure 1c :Estimated of cutting points

    a1

    85 90 95 00

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    1.2

    1.4

    1.6

    1.8

    a2

    85 90 95 00

    3

    4

    5

    6

    Estimates of cutting points

    a3

    85 90 95 00

    4

    5

    6

    7

    a4

    85 90 95 00

    5

    6

    7

    8

    a5

    85 90 95 00

    6

    7

    8

    9

    10

    11

    a6

    85 90 95 00

    11

    12

    13

    14

    15

    a7

    85 90 95 00

    12

    14

    16

    18

    20

    2

    2

    48

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    52/56

    Figure 2 Estimated means, constant cutting points

    89 91 93 95 97 99 01 035

    6

    7

    8

    9

    10

    11

    12

    13

    Year

    estimates

    m2

    m3

    m4

    m5

    m6

    m7

    49

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    53/56

    Figure 3 Estimated standard deviations, constant cutting points

    89 91 93 95 97 99 01 030

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    Year

    estimates

    2

    3

    4

    5

    6

    7

    50

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    54/56

    Figure 4 Smoothed latent variable

    Year

    1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

    -1.

    5

    -1.

    0

    -0.

    5

    0.

    0

    0.

    5

    1.

    0

    1.

    5

    51

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    55/56

    Figure 5 Evolution of downgrade probabilities

    time

    Probability

    1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

    0.0

    4

    0.0

    6

    0.0

    8

    0.1

    0

    0.1

    2

    0.1

    4

    0.1

    6

    0.1

    8

    AA

    time

    Probability

    1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

    0.0

    2

    0.0

    4

    0.0

    6

    0.0

    8

    0.1

    0

    A

    time

    Probability

    1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

    0.0

    2

    0.0

    4

    0.0

    6

    0.0

    8

    0.1

    0

    BBB

    time

    Probability

    1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

    0.0

    5

    0.1

    0

    0.1

    5

    BB

    time

    Probability

    1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

    0.0

    5

    0.1

    0

    0.1

    5

    0.2

    0

    B

    time

    Probability

    1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    CCC

    Figure 6 Means and predicted means

    89 94 99 045.55

    5.6

    5.65

    5.7

    5.75

    5.8

    5.85

    5.9AA

    Year

    Means

    Predictions

    89 94 99 046.51

    6.515

    6.52

    6.525

    6.53

    6.535

    6.54A

    Year

    Means

    Predictions

    89 94 99 046.9

    6.95

    7

    7.05

    7.1

    7.15BBB

    Year

    Means

    Predictions

    89 94 99 047.8

    7.85

    7.9

    7.95

    8BB

    Year

    Means

    Predictions

    89 94 99 049.5

    99

    10.5

    11

    11.5B

    Year

    Means

    Predictions

    89 94 99 0412.6

    12.65

    12.7

    12.75

    12.8

    12.85

    12.9

    12.95CCC

    Year

    Means

    Predictions

    52

  • 8/6/2019 Risk Rating Article 2004

    56/56

    Figure 7 Smoothed Factor Values

    Year

    Smoothed

    1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002-2.0

    -1.5

    -1.0

    -0.5

    0.0

    0.5

    1.0